NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES
THE FUTURE OF THE GOVERNMENT SPONSORED ENTERPRISES:
THE ROLE FOR GOVERNMENT IN THE U.S. MORTGAGE MARKET
Dwight Jaffee
John M. Quigley
Working Paper 17685
http://www.nber.org/papers/w17685
NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH
1050 Massachusetts Avenue
Cambridge, MA 02138
December 2011
We are grateful to the Fisher Center for Real Estate and Urban Economics at the University of California,
Berkeley, for financial support. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily
reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research.
NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-
reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official
NBER publications.
© 2011 by Dwight Jaffee and John M. Quigley. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed
two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice,
is given to the source.
The Future of the Government Sponsored Enterprises: The Role for Government in the U.S.
Mortgage Market
Dwight Jaffee and John M. Quigley
NBER Working Paper No. 17685
December 2011
JEL No. G01,G2,G28,H81,R21,R3
ABSTRACT
This paper analyzes options for reforming the U.S. housing finance system in view of the failure of
Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac as government sponsored enterprises (GSEs). The options considered
include GSE reform, a range of possible new governmental mortgage guarantee plans, and greater
reliance on private mortgage markets. The analysis also considers the likely consequences of adopting
alternative roles for government in the U.S. housing and mortgage markets. We start by reviewing
the history of the GSEs and their contributions to the operation of U.S. housing and mortgage markets,
including the actions that led to their failure in conjunction with the recent mortgage market crisis.
The reform options we consider include those proposed in a 2011 U.S. Treasury White Paper, plans
for new government mortgage guarantees from various researchers and organizations, and the evidence
from Western European countries for the efficacy of private mortgages markets.
Dwight Jaffee
Haas School of Business
University of California
Berkeley, CA 94720-1900
John M. Quigley
Department of Economics
Evans Hall #3880
University of California
Berkeley, CA 94720-3880
2
I. Introduction
The two large Government Sponsored Housing Enterprises (GSEs),
1
the Federal
National Mortgage Association (“Fannie Mae”) and the Federal Home Loan Mortgage
Corporation (“Freddie Mac”), evolved over three quarters of a century from a single
small government agency, to a large and powerful duopoly, and ultimately to insolvent
institutions protected from bankruptcy only by the full faith and credit of the U.S.
government. Between 2007 and Q2 2011, the two GSEs had realized losses of $247
billion, and they required draws of $169 billion under the Treasured Preferred Stock
Purchase Agreements to remain in operation. (See Federal Housing Finance Agency
2011). This paper traces the transformation of the GSEs from privately held institutions
with powerful direction and political influence to vassals reporting to an administrative
agency in the Department of Housing and Urban Development (the Federal Housing
Finance Agency, FHFA).
Within the next few years, the agencies will have to be restructured. Proposals for
reform include recapitalizing them in some form as Government Sponsored Enterprises
(GSEs), reconstituting them as agencies of the federal government with more narrowly-
specified missions, or privatizing the organizations. There are also proposals to replace
the GSEs with a variety of new government mortgage guarantee/insurance programs. The
GSE reform and mortgage guarantee proposals are both nested within the larger question
of what are the likely consequences of alternative roles for government in the U.S.
housing and mortgage markets. This paper is intended to help in the deliberations about
1
A third, much smaller, Government Sponsored Housing Enterprise is the Federal Home Loan Bank
System (FHLBS). The issues for reforming the FHLBS are similar to many of the issue raised in this paper
for Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, although we have not analyzed separately the FHLBS or other non-
housing government enterprises.
3
“what to do” about these costly failures. We briefly review the history of the housing
enterprises and their performance, including the recent housing crisis. We document the
contributions of Freddie and Fannie to the operation of U.S. housing markets, and we
analyze the role of the agencies in the recent housing crisis. We search for evidence on
the importance of Freddie and Fannie in achieving other important housing goals. We
compare U.S. policies with those adopted in other developed countries.
This is not the first time we have provided some analysis of the reform options in
housing finance, either individually (Jaffee, 2010b, 2011; Quigley 2006) or jointly (Jaffee
and Quigley, 2010). However, it is our first attempt to consider all the history and all of
the options.
In section II below we discuss the background and origin of the GSEs and of the
federal role in supplying housing credit. Section III provides a brief summary of
homeownership and government policy. Section IV describes the broader objectives and
goals of the GSE institutions and analyzes the most recent failures of the credit market
and the secondary housing market. Section V links the current housing crisis to the
insolvency of credit institutions. Section VI describes likely the consequences of a series
of plans concerning the restructuring of these institutions and alternative mechanisms for
government support of the U.S. mortgage market. It also provides a brief summary of the
GSEs under their government conservatorship since September 2008.
II. Background
With the public sale of its stock and its conversion into a government sponsored
enterprise in 1968, the Federal National Mortgage Association (FNMA) emerged from
obscurity as an agent in the market for home mortgage credit. The FNMA had been
4
established in 1938, based on provisions in the 1934 National Housing Act, after the
collapse of the housing market during the Great Depression. The 1934 Act had
established the Federal Housing Administration (FHA) to oversee a program of home
mortgage insurance against default. Insurance was funded by the proceeds of a fixed-
premium charged on unpaid loan balances. These revenues were deposited in Treasury
securities and managed as a mutual insurance fund. Significantly, default insurance was
offered on “economically sound” self-amortizing mortgages with terms as long as twenty
years and with loan-to-value ratios up to eighty percent.
Diffusion of the new FHA product across the country required national
standardization of underwriting procedures. Appraisals were required, and borrowers’
credit histories and financial capacities were reported and evaluated systematically. The
Mutual Mortgage Insurance Fund, established to manage the reserve of FHA premiums,
was required to be actuarially sound. This was generally understood to allow very small
redistributions from high income to low income FHA mortgagees. By its original design,
the FHA was clearly intended to serve the vast majority of homeowners.
In the 1934 Act, Congress had also sought to encourage private establishment of
National Mortgage Associations that would buy and sell the new and unfamiliar insured
mortgages of the Federal Housing Administration. By creating a secondary market for
these assets, the Associations sought to increase the willingness of primary lenders to
make these loans. No private associations were formed, however. When further
liberalization of the terms under which associations could be organized was still
unsuccessful, the Federal National Mortgage Association was chartered in 1938 by the
Federal Housing Administrator following the request of the President of the United
5
States. Federal action was precipitated particularly by concern over the acceptability of
new FHA ninety-percent twenty-five-year loans authorized that year.
At first, the Association operated on a small scale, but its willingness to buy FHA
mortgages encouraged lenders to make them. A 1948 authorization to purchase
mortgages guaranteed by the Veterans Administration led the Association to make
purchases, commitments, loans, and investments that soon approached the
congressionally authorized limit of $2.5 billion. Since the maximum interest rate on VA
mortgages was below the market rate, FNMA’s advance commitments to buy VA-
guaranteed mortgages at par assured windfall gains to private borrowers or lenders. The
1954 Housing Act reorganized Fannie Mae as a mixed-ownership corporation with
eligible shareholders being the federal government and lenders that sold mortgages to
Fannie Mae. FNMA was then able to finance its operations through sale of its preferred
stock to the U.S. Treasury, through sale of its common stock to lenders whose mortgages
it bought, and by the sale of bonds to the public.
The Housing and Urban Development Act of 1968 transferred FNMA’s special
assistance and the management and liquidation of part of its portfolio to the newly
constituted Government National Mortgage Association. Its secondary market operations
remained with FNMA, now owned entirely by private stockholders. Commercial banks
were the primary beneficiaries of FNMA’s secondary market activities in FHA and VA
mortgages -- since the banks specialized in originating the government-guaranteed
mortgages. In contrast, the mortgages originated by Savings and Loan Associations
(S&Ls) and Mutual Savings Banks (“Thrift Institutions”) were primarily “conventional”
mortgages, meaning they received no government guarantee. The thrift institutions
6
lobbied for equal treatment, and were rewarded in 1970 with the establishment of the
Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation (“Freddie Mac”) under the regulatory control
of the Federal Home Loan Bank System, the S&L regulator. Freddie Mac stock first
became publicly available in 1989, although shares owned by Freddie Mac’s financial
partners had been traded on the New York Stock Exchange starting in 1984.
III. Homeownership and Government Policy
According to de Tocqueville (1835), Americans have long been obsessed with
owner-occupied housing. Richard Green (2011) sees this as a political issue, as societies
are less disposed to make revolution when personal and real property is augmented and
distributed among the population. Other recent work emphasizes the external benefits of
owner-occupied housing, and a large social science literature has developed exploring the
connection between higher levels of homeownership and the economic and social
outcomes of households. Appendix Table A1 reports some of the findings linking
homeownership to social outcomes. Two other papers (Dietz and Haurin, 2003; Haurin,
Dietz and Weinberg, 2002) provide an exhaustive comparison of the economic and social
consequences for those living in owner-occupied and rental housing.
Most of the research supports the conclusion that homeownership has some
positive effects upon the social outcomes for individuals and households. But the
research does not conclude that the effect is very large. But even if the effect were large,
nothing supports the conclusion that homeownership should be supported by the
institution of the GSEs or their policy choices. In particular, the primary impact of
instruments that focus on lowering the cost or expanding the availability of mortgages
7
will be larger mortgages, which makes those instruments ineffective and costly relative to
direct subsidies for homeownership.
This is important -- for as noted below many of the popular arguments in support
of subsidies for the GSEs are based upon the promotion of homeownership in the
economy.
IV. Policy Objectives for the GSEs
A. Primary Objectives
The GSE charters are quite explicit in stating the goals and responsibilities of the
enterprises, but they do not state homeownership goals directly. Instead, they seek to:
1) provide stability in the secondary market for residential mortgages;
2) respond appropriately to the private capital market;
3) provide ongoing assistance to the secondary market for residential mortgages
(including activities relating to mortgages on housing for low- and moderate-income
families involving a reasonable economic return that may be less than the return earned
on other activities) by increasing the liquidity of mortgage investments and improving the
distribution of investment capital available for residential mortgage financing;
4) promote access to mortgage credit throughout the Nation (including central cities,
rural areas, and underserved areas) by increasing the liquidity of mortgage investments
and improving the distribution of investment capital available for residential mortgage
financing; and
5) manage and liquidate federally owned mortgage portfolios in an orderly manner,
with a minimum of adverse effect upon the residential mortgage market and minimum
loss to the Federal Government.
8
This section reviews the key activities of the GSEs with respect to providing
stability, assistance, and liquidity to the secondary market for residential mortgages. The
specific objectives of the secondary market activities have varied over time, including
operations to reinforce or offset fiscal and monetary policy, to increase residential
construction, to make a market in federally underwritten mortgages, to reduce regional
yield differentials, and to act as a mortgage lender of last resort. (See Guttentag, 1963, for
an extensive discussion of these key activities.)
A.1 Quantitative Impact of the GSEs on the U.S. Home Mortgage Market
Table 1 reviews the quantitative role of the GSEs in the US mortgage market over
the recent past. The top panel reports the outstanding amounts of whole home mortgages
at the end of each decade from 1950 through 2010. Through 1960, all whole home
mortgages were directly held in portfolios, and even by 1970 the only exception was $3
billion of mortgage-backed securities (MBS) issued by the newly established
Government National Mortgage Association (GNMA). The largest portfolio investor has
always been the set of depository institutions, commercial banks and thrift institutions
(savings and loan associations, savings banks, and credit unions).
2
The market investor
portfolios include capital market investors ranging from pension funds and mutual funds
to insurance companies. Starting in 1980, increasing amounts of whole home mortgages
have been held within MBS pools. The top panel of Table 1 separates the three main
categories of MBS pools: pools issued by the GSEs, by GNMA, and by private label
securitizers (PLS).
2
The GSE category covers the Fannie Mae on-balance-sheet portfolio through 1970 and the sum of the
Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac portfolios thereafter.
9
The middle panel of Table 1 shows each of the investor categories for whole
home mortgage holdings as a percentage of the total amount outstanding. One major
trend is apparent; portfolio holdings declined steadily from 100 percent of the total in
1960 to 37 percent of the total by 2010. Among the portfolio investors, both depository
institution and market investor holdings declined steadily starting in 1970. The GSE
portfolio holdings of whole home mortgages, five percent of the total in 2010, remained a
small percentage of the total throughout the history, with fluctuations within the narrow
band of three percent to eight percent of the total.
The second major trend reported in the middle panel of Table 1 is the steady rise
in mortgage pool holdings as a percentage of the total, starting at one percent in 1970 and
reaching 63 percent of the total by 2010. GSE pools show the most rapid rise, reaching 41
percent of total outstanding home mortgages by 2010. The PLS pools also grew steadily,
reaching twelve percent of the total by 2010. The GNMA pool share of total outstanding
mortgages, ten percent at year-end 2010, fluctuated in a narrow range between ten
percent and fifteen percent of the total from 1980 to the present.
The bottom panel of Table 1 shows the direct GSE share of the home mortgage
market, computed as the sum of whole mortgages held in the GSE portfolios and their
outstanding MBS. While this GSE share rose steadily from 1950, the primary increase
started in 1990, with the share reaching 46 percent of all outstanding home mortgages in
2010. This direct share does not include MBS from other issuers that were held in the
GSE portfolios, a topic to which we turn below.
3
3
Quantitatively, including the GSE holdings of other MBS would raise the total GSE share to 47 percent
and 48 percent for 2000 and 2010 respectively. This ratio actually peaked in 2003, reaching fifty percent.
10
While Table 1 accounts for all outstanding home mortgages, it does not
distinguish among the investor groups holding the MBS instruments created by the
mortgage pools. This issue is addressed in Table 2, in which ownership of the MBS pools
has been allocated among the various investor classes. These values are then combined
with the portfolio holdings of whole mortgages to determine the ownership structure of
all home mortgages, whether held as whole mortgages or as investment in MBS pools.
4
It
is apparent from Table 2 that, starting in 1980, market investors were expanding relative
to the depository institutions and the GSEs, and that by 2010 the market investors were
the largest investor class for the sum of whole mortgages and mortgage securities.
Figure 1 reports the percentage of outstanding whole mortgages held directly in
portfolios for each of the three investor classes. The depository institutions have always
been the predominant holder of whole mortgages. At year-end 2010, the depository
institutions held 76 percent of all whole mortgages that were directly held in portfolios,
with the market investors and the GSEs each holding a twelve percent share.
Figure 2 reports the percentage of outstanding MBS for the three holder classes.
5
It is apparent that the market investors have always been dominant in holding MBS
positions. At year-end 2010, market investors were holding 67 percent of the outstanding
MBS, with depository institutions holding 21 percent and the GSEs twelve percent.
Figure 3 combines the results for Figures 1 and 2, reporting the share for each
holder class of their combined positions in whole mortgages and MBS. By 2010, the
market investors had the largest position, representing 47 percent of all home mortgages,
4
As far as we are aware, this integration of whole mortgage portfolio holdings and MBS pools by investor
has not been available previously.
5
The graphs start in 1970, since there were no outstanding MBS before that year.
11
with depository institutions in the second position, holding 41 percent of all home
mortgages. At the same time, the GSEs were holding twelve percent of all home
mortgages (as either whole mortgages or MBS) a share just below their average over the
last three decades.
Figure 3 indicates that the GSE combined holdings of whole mortgages and MBS
has always represented a relatively small share of total U.S. home mortgages outstanding.
In this sense, closing the GSEs now, in an orderly way, would have a minor impact on the
U.S. mortgage market. That is, the twelve percent GSE share could be readily replaced by
a combination of market investors and depository institutions (who are already holding
88 percent of U.S. home mortgages). There are, however, two other measures of potential
GSE benefits with regard to outstanding whole mortgages and MBS: (1) the contribution
of MBS issued by the GSEs, and (2) stabilization of the U.S. home mortgage market
through countercyclical activities by the GSEs. We now consider these in turn.
A.2 The Role of GSE-Issued MBS
Figure 4 shows the relative shares of outstanding home mortgage MBS by issuer
class. The GSE share has been dominant since 1990, representing 65 percent of all
outstanding MBS in 2010. The share of private label securitizers (PLS) has been steadily
rising, but still represented only 19 percent of outstanding MBS at year-end 2010. The
GNMA share has been steadily declining, reaching a 16 percent market share by year-end
2010.
The dominant historical position of GSE MBS in the current U.S. home mortgage
is sometimes used to justify a future role for the GSEs in the market. But, at its core, the
GSE dominance of the MBS market for home mortgages has been largely derived from
12
the assumption of market investors—reinforced by GSE marketing--that the GSE MBS
had an implicit government guarantee (and which turned out to be correct, after
imposition of the GSE Conservatorships in 2008). In this sense, the dominant GSE MBS
position is just an example of crowding out, whereby any asset with a low-cost
government guarantee against loss will likely replace private activity in the same market.
If the government guarantee were eliminated, there is every reason to expect that private
market activity would simply replace the activity of the government entity.
A brief review of the history of U.S. MBS development is valuable for
understanding the limited contribution of the GSEs to MBS innovations:
6
1968: GNMA creates first modern MBS by securitizing FHA/VA mortgages;
1970s: GSEs expand MBS market based on their implicit government guarantee;
7
1980s: Salomon Bros. securitizes multi-class, non-guaranteed, MBS instruments;
8
1990s: Multi-class (structured finance) mechanism is first applied to wide range of
asset-backed securities, including auto, credit card, and commercial mortgage loans;
2000s: Subprime lending becomes the most important application of MBS/ABS
methods.
6
US mortgage securitization probably actually began soon after the founding of the Republic. Following
the war of 1812, the US federal government was desperate for revenue and extended loans to homesteaders
for property on the Western frontiers. Without the resources to make and hold these loans, the government
pooled and sold these loans to investors. By the 1920s, securitization was already a well accepted format
for selling loans to investors. These mortgage-backed securities failed during the real estate crisis of the
1930s, and it was decades before U.S. securitization was reactivated in 1968. See Quinn (2010) for a new
history of the U.S. housing policy and the origins of securitization.
7
The GSEs could point to their $2.25 billion line of credit at the US Treasury as backing for their
guarantee, a significant factor only in the early years when their scale of operations was relatively small. It
also helped the GSE case that the US government never firmly and officially rejected the notion of an
implicit guarantee.
8
The colorful development of private-label MBS under Lewis Ranieri at Solomon Brothers is wonderfully
chronicled in Liars Poker by Lewis (1990).
13
Credit for the modern innovation of single-class MBS belongs to the government
itself with the creation of the GNMA MBS. GNMA was, and remains, an agency within
the Department of Housing and Urban Development. Likewise, credit for the innovation
of the multi-class MBS belongs to the private sector with the development of structured
MBS by Salomon Bros. in the 1980s. In fact, the GSEs have always been followers, not
innovators, in the MBS market. The success of the GSEs in establishing the market for
their own MBS depended entirely on the perception of capital market investors that they
faced no credit risk as the result of the implicit federal guarantee. Absent this government
guarantee, the single-class GSE MBS would have simply lost out in the marketplace to
the multi-class, private-label, MBS.
GSE proponents often argue that the GSEs reduced securitization costs and
mortgage interest rates. Here, too, the reality is that the GSEs provide no benefit other
than the implicit guarantee. A case in point is the TBA (“to be announced”) forward
market for GSE and GNMA MBS. While this market arguably expands the liquidity of
the traded MBS, the benefit depends completely on the market’s perception that the
guarantees—explicit for GNMA and implicit for the GSE MBS—make credit risk
irrelevant in the pricing and trading of the securities. It is equally noteworthy that the
markets for asset-backed securitization, for the securitization of credit card, auto, and
commercial mortgage loans, and other loan classes as well, expanded rapidly starting in
the early 1990s without any contribution from the GSEs. Indeed, as with the original
GNMA MBS, the GSEs benefited from the innovation by others, creating their own
14
structured finance offerings once the market demand for such securities had been
expanded through private market innovation.
9
Finally, the claim is sometimes made that the GSE MBS activity is critical for the
survival of the thirty-year, fixed-rate, residential mortgage. This claim is unwarranted. In
fact, two features of the GSE MBS instrument were clearly detriments to the expansion
of the long-term, fixed-rate, mortgage:
First, the GSE MBS transferred the entire interest rate risk imbedded in the fixed-
rate mortgages to the market investors who purchased the instruments. The GSEs took no
action to mitigate this risk;
Second, the GSE MBS generally disallowed prepayment penalties on all the
mortgages they securitized. While borrowers may have felt they benefitted from this
“free” call option, it greatly magnified the interest rate risk imposed on investors in the
GSE MBS, and led to higher interest rates on the fixed-rate mortgages.
Finally, a number of Western European countries successfully use long-term,
fixed rate, mortgages, but have no entity comparable to the GSEs, Denmark is the most
conspicuous example. The use of covered bonds allows European banks to hold long-
term mortgages on their balance sheets, while passing a substantial part of the interest-
rate risk to capital market investors. We further discuss the experience of Western
European countries in Section A5 below.
9
See Downing, Jaffee, and Wallace (2009) for a discussion of how the GSEs profited by restructuring their
simple passthrough MBS into more complex multi-tranche securitizations.
15
A.3 The Limited GSE Contributions to Mortgage Market Stability
The GSEs also claim credit for taking actions to stabilize the U.S. mortgage
markets. The U.S. Government Accountability Office (2009), however, finds little
evidence of such benefits:
“… the extent to which the enterprises have been able to support a stable
and liquid secondary mortgage market during periods of economic stress,
which are key charter and statutory obligations, is not clear. In 1996, we
attempted to determine the extent to which the enterprises’ activities
would support mortgage finance during stressful economic periods by
analyzing Fannie Mae’s mortgage activities in some states, including oil
producing states such as Texas and Louisiana, beginning in the 1980s.
Specifically, we analyzed state-level data on Fannie Mae’s market shares
and housing price indexes for the years 1980–1994. We did not find
sufficient evidence that Fannie Mae provided an economic cushion to
mortgage markets in those states during the period analyzed.”
Reports by the Congressional Budget Office (1996, 2010) come to similar conclusions.
The academic literature also generally concludes that the GSE contribution to U.S.
mortgage market stability has been modest at best. This view is stated in early studies by
Jaffee and Rosen (1978, 1979) and more recent studies by Frame and White (2005) and
Lehnert, Passmore, and Sherlund (2008). In contrast, Naranjo and Toevs (2002), a study
funded by Fannie Mae, found evidence of effective stabilization by the GSEs, as did
other studies carried out internally by the GSEs. Unlike the previous studies, Peek and
Wilcox (2003) focused on the flow of mortgage funds, and not on mortgage interest rates,
and found the GSE contribution to be countercyclical. Of course, this research was all
conducted before the subprime housing bubble and its collapse. In this event, as we now
document, the GSE participation was decidedly destabilizing.
A.4 The GSE Role in the Subprime Mortgage Boom and Crash
The losses reported by the GSEs starting in 2008 leave no doubt that the GSEs
acquired a significant volume of risky mortgages during the subprime boom. However,
16
the extent, timing, and significance of these acquisitions is debated. For example, Jaffee
(2010) describes the GSE role as “expanding” the subprime boom, especially in 2007,
whereas Wallison (2011, p.2) concludes that GSE activity, based on their housing goals,
was a primary “source” of the crisis. In this section, we evaluate the role played by the
GSEs in the subprime mortgage boom and crash.
A quantitative evaluation of the GSE role in the subprime crisis faces a number of
significant data issues:
1) Definitions for subprime and Alt A mortgages differ across data sets, and certain high-
risk mortgages are not included under either label.
2) Defining high-risk mortgages (including subprime and Alt A instruments) is
necessarily complex because mortgage default risk arises from numerous factors
including borrower and property attributes (FICO scores, loan-to-value ratios, etc.),
special amortization options (interest only, negative amortization, etc.), and fixed-rate
versus adjustable-rate loans.
3) The GSEs could not acquire any mortgages with an initial loan amount above the
conforming loan limit (so-called jumbo mortgages).
Our analysis starts by reviewing a newly compiled mortgage origination dataset
from the GSE regulator, the Federal Housing Finance Agency (2010a).
10
These data
compare the risk characteristics of all mortgages acquired by the GSEs (whether
securitized or held in retained portfolios) with the risk characteristics of all conforming,
conventional, mortgages that were included in private label securitizations (PLS),
tabulated by year of mortgage origination. Because the dataset has nearly complete
coverage and is restricted to conforming mortgages, it provides the best available direct --
10
We thank Robin Seiler of the Federal Housing Finance Agency for providing us with a roadmap for the
intricacies of these data.
17
“apples to apples” -- comparison of the GSE acquired mortgages relative to the
comparable market. Nevertheless, there are two limitations. First, while the FHFA data
include all the conforming mortgages that collateralized PLS MBS instruments, the GSE
holdings of PLS tranches are not so identified. We do not expect a significant bias in the
comparisons from this source, however, because the GSE PLS holdings were almost
entirely AAA tranches with little ex ante credit risk.
11
Second, the FHFA data exclude
conforming mortgages that were not securitized (i.e., they were retained in lender
portfolios). To the extent that lenders did retain conforming mortgages with high-risk
attributes, the FHFA dataset will undercount the high-risk dimensions of the overall
conforming origination pools, and will therefore overstate the GSE share of all high-risk
originations. Here too, we do not expect a significant bias in our comparisons, because
most subprime and Alt-A mortgages were securitized, and the securitization rate was
even higher among those high-risk loans that were also conforming mortgages.
12
Panel A of Table 3 shows the dollar amount of the conforming mortgages by
origination year and various risk attributes. Rows (1) to (3) report on loans with one of
the identified high-risk factors: high loan-to-value (LTV) ratios, low FICO scores, and
adjustable rate mortgages (ARMs) respectively. However, there is some double counting
11
See Thomas and Van Order (2011) for further discussion. PLS tranches as a share of total GSE
acquisitions reached its high point at 22.9 percent in 2005, but had fallen to 7.4 percent by 2007.
Furthermore, actual cash flow losses on GSE PLS positions have been modest to date, although the GSEs
have recognized significant mark to market valuation losses on these positions.
12
For example, 2007 data from Inside Mortgage Finance indicate that only $33 billion (or 7%) of the
subprime/Alt A mortgages originated that year were not securitized. Even if these were all conforming
mortgages, their share of total conforming originations that year would be less than 3 percent. Furthermore,
Inside Mortgage Finance indicates that over 31% of subprime MBS and 9 percent of Alt A MBS in 2007
were “GSE eligible”—i.e. conforming mortgages eligible for GSE purchase--further reducing the incentive
of portfolio lenders to hold these mortgages in unsecuritized form. It is also noteworthy that while there is
no consensus conclusion from the expanding literature on whether securitization created lax underwriting
standards—see for example the contrast between Bubb and Kaufman (2009) and Keys etal. (2010)—there
is no finding that portfolio lenders were systematically retaining high-risk mortgages.
18
since some loans have more than one of these attributes. The aggregate high-risk
originations shown in row (4) net out all double counting.
13
Row (6) shows the
percentage of high-risk mortgages as a share of total conforming mortgages (in row 5).
This high-risk share of total conforming originations rose steadily through 2004 and then
declined steadily thereafter.
Panel B of Table 3 computes the share of the conforming mortgages acquired by
the GSEs—whether as backing for guaranteed MBS or to hold on their balance sheets--
for each risk attribute. For example, in 2001, the GSEs acquired about 92.2 percent of all
conforming mortgages with LTV ratios above 90 percent. For all 3 of the risk attributes,
the GSE share fell steadily through 2005 and then expanded rapidly through 2007. By
2007, the GSEs were acquiring 79.9 percent of the high-risk, conforming, mortgage
originations. In interpreting these numbers, however, it must be recognized that, as shown
in row (11), the GSEs represent a large share of the overall conforming mortgage market;
as their overall market share approaches 100 percent, their share of each risk attribute
would necessarily do the same.
Panel C corrects for the large GSE share of the conforming market by computing
a “relative intensity,” dividing the GSE market share for each risk attribute in Panel B by
the overall GSE market share in Row (11). A coefficient of one indicates the GSEs are
holding the “market portfolio,” whereas coefficients below one indicate they are avoiding
risky mortgages and coefficients above one indicate the GSEs are actively acquiring risky
mortgages. The pattern for each of the three risk attributes shows the relative intensity
13
For example, for the fixed-rate mortgage originations in 2007, 2.2 percent had LTV > 90 percent and
FICO score < 620. For adjustable rate mortgages in 2007, 19.2 percent had either LTV > 90 percent or
FICO score < 620. Overall, in 2007 4.7 percent of the originated mortgages had more than one of the high-
risk attributes.
19
rising steadily starting in 2005. In each case, the high point of the seven-year history was
reached in 2007. Since the relative intensities over the full time span are generally less
than one, it would appear the GSEs were not leading the market for high-risk lending as
the subprime boom took off.
14
But the jumps in the relative intensities in 2007 for most of
the indicators suggest that the GSEs then rapidly expanded their participation in the
subprime boom. This is one key basis for our conclusion that the GSEs were a
destabilizing influence on the conforming mortgage market as the subprime boom headed
to its peak in 2007.
The analysis has so far focused on the GSE acquisition of high-risk mortgages as
a share of the overall conforming mortgage market. We now consider the GSE
acquisition of high risk mortgages as a share of their total acquisitions. Table 4 reports
the first three attributes high LTV ratios; low FICO scores; and ARMs; as reported in
Table 3. The time pattern is again distinctive, with the share of the GSEs new business
dedicated to mortgages with these high-risk attributes generally rising starting in 2004,
the only exception being the declining share of ARM acquisitions by Fannie Mae. The
companies also reported their acquisitions of interest-only, condo/coop, and investor
mortgages; and here too the pattern is generally rising from 2004. 2007 represents the
year of maximum share for each high-risk mortgage attribute with the exception of
Fannie Mae ARMs and Freddie Mac interest-only mortgages. These data thus present a
second independent basis for our conclusion that the GSEs were a decidedly destabilizing
influence on the conforming mortgage market as the subprime boom headed to its peak in
2007.
14
Thomas and Van Order (2011), although using different datasets, come to the same conclusion.
20
A.5 Mortgage Markets Without GSEs
The analysis above leaves little doubt that the GSEs destabilized the U.S.
mortgage market during the later stages of the subprime boom, but there is a further
question how the U.S. mortgage markets would function without the GSEs. To help
answer this, in this section we consider evidence from two sources: (1) how the U.S.
mortgage markets have performed without GSEs, and (2) the performance of the
mortgage markets in Western European countries.
The evidence that private mortgage markets have operated effectively in the U.S.
economy can be summarized with three comments on the historical role of private
markets within the U.S. mortgage market. First, private markets have always originated
100% of U.S. mortgages, and closing the GSEs would not affect this. Second, the GSEs
have never held a significant share of the outstanding U.S. home mortgages, this share
being, for example, 12 percent at year-end 2010. Third, the GSE MBS share of total
home mortgages first exceeded 30% only in 2007. This confirms that the private
markets—depository institutions and capital market investors--are capable of holding or
securitizing the large majority of U.S. mortgages. It is also noteworthy that the market for
jumbo mortgages—mortgages that exceed the conforming loan limit--has generally
functioned quite satisfactorily.
Turning to the European evidence, the European economies and housing markets
are sufficiently similar to the U.S. to provide a potentially interesting comparison, while
they have the key distinction that government intervention in these housing and mortgage
markets is far less than for the U.S.; in particular, none of these countries has entities with
21
any significant resemblance to the U.S. GSEs.
15
This conclusion is stated very clearly by
Coles and Hardt (2000, p. 778):
16
“There is no national or European government agency to help lenders fund
their loans. Mortgage loans have to be funded on the basis of the financial
strength of banks or the intrinsic quality of the securities. EU Law (Article
87 and 88 of the EC treaty) outlaws state aid in the form of guarantees as
there may be an element of competitive distortion.”
Table 5 compares the U.S. and Western European mortgage markets for a range
of quantitative attributes from 1998 to 2010 based on a comprehensive data base of
housing and mortgage data for fifteen European countries from the European Mortgage
Federation (2010). Column 1 compares the most recent owner occupancy rates for the
U.S. and European countries. The U.S. value is 66.9 percent, which is just below its peak
subprime boom value. It is frequently suggested that the high rate of homeownership is
the result of the large U.S. government support of the mortgage market, including the
GSEs. It is thus highly revealing that the U.S. rate is just at the median— eight of the
European countries have higher owner occupancy rates—and slightly below the average
value for the European countries. Furthermore, the lower owner occupancy rates in some
of the countries, Germany for example, appear to be the result of cultural preferences
rather than government inaction. A full analysis of the determinants of owner occupancy
rates across countries should also control for the age distribution of the population, since
younger households, and possibly the oldest households, may have lower ownership rates
in all countries. Chirui and Jappelli (2003) provide a start in this direction, showing that
lower downpayment rates are a significant factor encouraging owner occupancy after
15
See European Central Bank (2009) for an extensive review of housing finance in the European Union
countries.
16
Hardt was the Secretary General of the European Mortgage Federation at the time.
22
controlling for the population age structure in a sample of fourteen OCED countries. The
U.S. has also generally benefitted from very low downpayment rates, but it still has an
average ownership rate, reinforcing the conclusion that the government interventions
have been largely ineffective in raising the U.S. home ownership rate relative to its peers.
Column 2 measures the volatility of housing construction activity from 1998 to
2010 based on the coefficient of variation of housing starts as a measure of relative
volatility. The U.S. relative volatility is third highest out of the 16 countries, implying
that the government interventions have failed to reduce U.S. housing cycles relative to
those in Western Europe. Column 3 measures the volatility of house price changes based
on the standard deviation of the annual house price appreciation from 1998 through 2010.
Here the U.S. stands fifth, meaning the country has faced a relatively high rate of house
price volatility. This negative result is all the more significant because the U.S. is far
larger than any of the individual European countries, and thus the benefits of regional
diversification should have lowered the observed U.S. volatility.
Column 4 compares the level of mortgage interest rates in Western Europe and
the U.S., using “representative variable mortgage rates” for Europe and the Freddie Mac
one-year ARM commitment rate for the U.S. The column shows that the U.S. has the
sixth highest average mortgage interest rate from 1998 to 2010, and exceeds the Western
European average by 27 basis points. Since overall interest rates also vary across
countries, as a further test, column 5 shows the average spread between the mortgage rate
and the Treasury bill rate for each country. The U.S. ranks third highest based on the
spread and exceeds the Western European average by 70 basis points. Of course,
numerous factors determine these mortgage rates and spreads, including the precise terms
23
of the variable rate mortgages, other contract features such as downpayment
requirements, and the generally greater credit risk of U.S. mortgages. Nevertheless, the
fact remains that despite the government subsidies and other interventions in the U.S.
residential mortgage markets, U.S. mortgage rates have remained among the highest
levels compared with the countries of Western Europe. Finally, Column 6 shows the
20109 ratio of home mortgages outstanding to each country’s annual GDP, a standard
measure of the depth of a country’s mortgage market. The U.S. ratio is 75.5 percent
which puts it sixth within this group of sixteen developed economies. A relatively high
U.S. result would be expected, given the large mortgage subsidies provided through the
GSEs and other channels. It is noteworthy, therefore, that five Western European
countries achieved even higher ratios without substantial government interventions in
their mortgage markets
The overall conclusion has to be that Western European mortgage and housing
markets have outperformed the U.S. markets over the full range of available measures.
Although data are not provided here, a similar conclusion would hold for the Australian
and Canadian mortgage markets; see Lea (2010). There are, of course, a wide range of
possible explanations for the superior performance of the European mortgage markets.
The key point for present purposes is simply that the superior performance of the
European mortgage markets is not explained by greater government intervention. In the
absence of GSEs, almost all Western European mortgage lending is carried out privately
by banks, primarily funded by bank deposits or covered bonds. Other indirect forms of
government support, such as the tax deductibility of mortgage interest and property taxes
are also notably absent in most European countries.
24
B. Other Justifications for GSE Subsidies
The activities of the GSEs are justified by the particular benefits accruing to
specific classes of borrowers, or more specifically, to all home purchasers and
homeowners from the activities supported by these institutions. As noted above, benefits
have been claimed for the stabilization of the mortgage supply and corresponding
reductions in the volatility of housing construction and home sales. But there are at least
three other classes of potential benefits arising from the GSE:
Increases in the extent of mortgage credit accruing to income and demographic
groups that policy-makers appear to have deemed particularly deserving -- credit which
augments that supplied by the private marketplace;
Increases in the lending support provided to builders, owners, or residents of
specific types of housing, e.g., multifamily rental housing, which would otherwise not be
provided in the market;
Subsidies accruing more broadly to housing market participants, for example, to
all home purchasers in the form of lower interest costs arising from the increased
liquidity afforded by the GSEs and the implicit guarantee of repayment provided by those
institutions;
This section reviews the evidence on the extent and distribution of these benefits.
1. Increased Credit to Targeted Groups and Geographical Areas
The original charter establishing Fannie Mae as a GSE in 1968 recognized a
“national goal of providing adequate housing for low and moderate income households,”
and it authorized the Secretary of the Department of Housing and Urban Development
(HUD) to require that a reasonable portion of Fannie Mae’s purchases of home
25
mortgages be related to this goal. Although regulations requiring the GSEs to allocate a
fixed percentage of mortgage purchases to lower-income households were advanced in
the 1970s, mandatory rules were not proposed in Congress until after the passage of the
Financial Institutions Reform, Recovery, and Enforcement Act (FIRREA) of 1989.
Ultimately, the Federal Housing Enterprises Financial Safety and Soundness Act of 1992
modified and made more explicit the “housing goals” to be promoted by the GSEs. The
Act directed the HUD Secretary to establish quantitative goals for mortgages to “low-
and moderate-income” households and for mortgages originated in “underserved areas.”
It also imposed a “special affordable housing goal” for mortgages for low-income
housing in low-income areas. The 1992 legislation stipulated two-year transition goals,
but after that period, the HUD Secretary was empowered to promulgate more detailed
regulations.
Under the HUD regulations, finalized in December 1995, the first goal (“low- and
moderate-income housing”) directs that a specified fraction of new loans purchased each
year by the GSEs be originated by households with incomes below the area median. The
second goal (“underserved areas”) requires that a specified fraction of mortgages be
originated in census tracts with median incomes less than 90 percent of the area median,
or else in census tracts with a minority population of at least 30 percent and with a tract
median income of less than 120 percent of area median income. The third goal (“special
affordable housing”) targets mortgages originated in tracts with family incomes less than
60 percent of the area median; or else mortgages in tracts with incomes less than 80
percent of area median and also located in specific low-income areas. Any single
mortgage can “count” towards more than one of these goals. (For example, any loan that
26
meets the “special affordable housing” goal also counts towards the “low- and moderate-
income” goal.)
The numerical goals originally set by HUD for 1996 were modest – requiring, for
example, that 40 percent of the GSEs’ mortgage purchases be loans made to households
with incomes below the area median. Over time, the goals for new business set by HUD
have been increased.
17
The goal for mortgages to low- and moderate-income households
has been increased from 40 percent in 1996 to 56 percent by 2008. Until 2007, mortgage
originations by both Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac had reached their primary goals every
year. The HUD goal for “underserved areas” was increased from 21 percent in 1996 to 39
percent in 2008. Originations by the larger GSE, Fannie Mae, exceeded this goal in every
year; originations by Freddie Mac exceeded the goal in each year until 2008. The “special
affordable” housing goal was increased by HUD from 12 percent in 1996 to 27 percent in
2008. Both GSEs surpassed this goal in loan originations each year until 2008.
Figures 5, 6, and 7 report the HUD goals and GSE progress in achieving those
goals from their publication in 1995 to the federal takeover of the GSEs in 2008.
Figures 8, 9, and 10 provide another perspective on the magnitude of the goals set
by HUD for the GSEs. They report each of the three goals as well as an estimate of the
share of all newly-issued mortgages in each of the categories. For example, in 2000 the
HUD-specified “low- and moderate-income goal” was to reach 42 percent of new
purchases for the GSEs. However, in 2000 low- and moderate-income mortgages,
according to the same definition, constituted about 59 percent of all new mortgages. At
17
Note, however, that at the time that the 1992 act was debated in Congress, only 36 percent of Fannie
Mae’s single-family deliveries were for housing whose value was below the area median. (See FHFA
Mortgage Market Note, The Housing Goals of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, February 1, 2010.)
27
that time, the “underserved areas” goal was 21 percent of GSE mortgages, while these
mortgages constituted more than a 30 percent market share of new mortgages. In virtually
all cases, the goals imposed were a good bit lower than the share of mortgage loans of
that type originated in the economy. There is no evidence that the goals were set so that
the GSEs would “lead the market” in servicing these groups of households.
2. Increased Credit to Targeted Housing Types: Multifamily
Numerical goals for purchases of multifamily mortgages are not mentioned in the
Financial Safety and Soundness Act of 1992, but there was considerable concern at the
time that the GSEs were not financing their “fair share” of multifamily housing,
especially small multifamily properties. For example, in 1991, small multifamily units
accounted for less than five percent of Freddie Mac’s multifamily unit purchases. At that
time, small multifamily units constituted 39 percent of all recently-financed multifamily
units. (See Herbert, 2001.) Thus, the first rules for implementing the 1992 Act put
forward by HUD also included explicit goals for multifamily housing.
These goals have been in the form of dollar-based targets. Goals in 1996-2000
were approximately 0.8 percent of the mortgage purchases of Fannie Mae and Freddie
Mac recorded in 1994; goals in 2001-2004 (2005-2007) were 1.0 percent of each GSE’s
estimated mortgage purchases in 1997-1999 (2000-2002). Beyond the achievement of
these numerical goals, multifamily mortgage purchases also qualified for “bonus points”
towards the achievement of the three goals specified in the 1992 law. It has been argued
that these “bonus points” (discontinued in 2004) were a major inducement leading to an
increase in participation by the GSEs in the multifamily housing market, particularly in
their financing of small multifamily properties. (See Manchester, 2007.)
28
Figure 11 reports the dollar goals for multifamily dwellings specified by HUD
regulations and the performance of each of the GSEs. As noted in the figure, until quite
recently purchases of multifamily dwellings exceeded the HUD goal by a substantial
amount.
V. Broad Benefits to Homeowners and Purchasers
a. The Effectiveness of the GSE Goals in Directing Mortgage Credit
Of course, the finding that the GSEs have achieved the annual goals specified in
regulations need not imply that Freddie and Fannie have been very effective in increasing
mortgage credit to targeted groups. For example, many suggest that the numerical goals
set for the GSEs have been far too low (e.g., Weicher, 2010), and that, as a result the
GSEs have simply followed the market with a lag of a few years. Indeed, the data in
Figures 5, 6 and 7, provide no evidence that Freddie Mac or Fannie Mae purchased more
than their “fair share” of mortgages in any of these areas of congressional concern. GSE
purchases of mortgages that satisfied any of these congressional goals – as a fraction of
all new purchases – were consistently smaller than their “market share” in all newly-
issued mortgages.
Similarly, Figure 11 indicates that the GSEs’ new purchases of “special
multifamily” mortgages greatly exceeded the dollar goals mandated by HUD in every
year.
Finally, Figure 12 demonstrates that the GSEs’ multifamily housing business was
only a small fraction of the mortgage purchases of the GSEs in any year. It never
amounted to even seven percent of either GSEs’ purchases.
29
Figure 13 reports the aggregate amount of commercial mortgage backed security
(CMBS) and multifamily originations between 2003 and 2009 as reported by the
Mortgage Bankers of America. Mortgage originations by Freddie Mac and Fannie Mae
were small – less than $9 billion in any year. Until 2008, GSE originations were less than
twenty percent of all such mortgage banker mortgage originations. Note, however that in
2008-2009, CMBS and commercial banks left the market entirely; originations by life
insurers declined as well. Since the conservatorship in 2008, virtually all multifamily
mortgages have been originated by the GSEs.
These simple comparisons suggest that any causal effect of the GSEs on lending
to specific income classes, neighborhoods, and property types is not likely to be large –at
least before 2008. Economic analysis of the potential impacts of the GSEs is also
complicated by other public programs in effect. For example, in 1977, the Community
Reinvestment Act (CRA) was passed to encourage banks to exert further efforts to meet
the credit needs of their local communities, including lower-income areas. In identifying
neighborhoods of special concern in administering the CRA, neighborhoods (census
tracts) with median incomes below 80 percent of the area median income are targeted. As
noted above, “underserved areas” of concern in GSE regulation are census tracts with
median incomes below 90 percent of the area median income. In addition, many
borrowers targeted under GSE criteria are also eligible for Federal Housing
Administration (FHA) loans or Veterans’ Administration (subsidized) loans.
The existence of parallel government programs under the CRA, FHA, and VA
raises the possibility that the GSE purchases of qualifying mortgages simply displaced
lenders who would have made the same mortgage under one of the other programs. To
30
the extent that this has been the case, the GSE purchases would have had no noticeable
impact on the mortgage market for the qualifying borrowers. Of course, it is a subtle
empirical problem to determine whether the GSE purchases were simply displacing loans
from the other programs. Nevertheless, a number of academic papers have sought to
identify and quantify the effects of the GSE goals on local and neighborhood housing
markets and on classes of borrowers.
Table 6 summarizes much of this research.
An early paper by Canner, Passmore and Surette (1996) examined loans eligible
for insurance under the FHA. The authors evaluated how the risk associated with these
loans is distributed among government mortgage institutions, private mortgage insurers,
the GSEs, and banks’ in-house portfolios. The results indicated that FHA bears the
largest risk share associated with lending to lower-income and minority populations, with
the GSEs lagging far behind. Bostic and Gabriel (2006) analyzed the effects of the GSE
mortgage purchase goals upon homeownership and housing conditions in California. A
careful comparison of neighborhoods just above the GSE cutoff for “low-moderate-
income” and “special affordable” designation with nearby neighborhoods just below the
cutoff found essentially no differences in the levels and differences in home-ownership
rates and housing conditions during the decade of the 1990s.
In a more sophisticated analysis using a similar comparison of neighborhoods
“just above” and “just below” the GSE cutoff, An, et al, (2007) focused on three
indicators of local housing markets: the home ownership rate, the vacancy rate, and the
median home value. The authors related (an instrument for) the intensity of GSE activity
in a census tract to these outcomes, using a variety of control variables. The results
31
indicated that increases in GSE purchase intensity were associated with significant but
very small declines in neighborhood vacancy rates and increases in median house values.
The authors conclude that the “results do not indicate much efficacy of the GSE
affordable housing loan-purchase targets in improving housing market conditions (2007,
p. 235).”
Two papers by Bhutta (2009b, 2010) adopted a regression discontinuity design to
test the effects of the “underserved areas” goal upon the supply of credit to those areas.
Rather than attempt to match similar neighborhoods for statistical analysis, Bhutta
exploited the facts that census tracts qualified for CRA scrutiny if their median incomes
were 80 percent of the local area, and they qualified for scrutiny under the HUD GSE
goals if their median incomes were 90 percent of the area median design. Bhutta merged
tract-level data on mortgages (from the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act) with
neighborhood (census) data. Bhutta’s results (2009a) do find a significant effect of the
“underserved area” goal on GSE purchasing activity – but the effect is very small (2-3
percent during the 1997-2002 period).
A more recent paper by Moulton (2010), also using a regression discontinuity
approach, finds no effect of the GSEs -- on individual loans rather than aggregate credit
allocations. Moulton uses micro data on mortgage loan applications to examine whether
the GSE’s affordable housing goals altered the probability that a loan application was
originated by a mortgage lending institution or that a loan was purchased by one of the
GSEs. The analysis led to the conclusion that the GSE affordable housing goal had no
effect at all on mortgage lending or on GSE purchases.
32
The consistent finding of little or no effect of the GSE goals on housing
outcomes, mortgage applications, or mortgage finance could suggest that there is little
effect of the GSE rules upon FHA lending as well. But several papers have reported that
an increased market share of GSE mortgages in a census tract is associated with a decline
in the FHA share of mortgages (An and Bostic, 2008; Gabriel and Rosenthal, 2010).
These results may explain why the increases in lending mandated by the HUD
regulations to achieve the congressional goals of the 1992 Act have had very little net
impact on housing and neighborhood outcomes. Small increases in GSE activity have
been offset by roughly comparable declines in FHA activity.
The extent to which an expansion of GSE activity simply crowds out private
mortgage purchases remains an open research question. For example, Gabriel and
Rosenthal (2010) argue that increased GSE activity in the mortgage market involved little
or no crowd-out until about 2005. After that, GSE activity crowded out private activity
until the crash in mortgage markets in 2007.
But even if there were a complete crowd-out of private mortgage activity arising
from GSE behavior , it is hard to attribute any of this to the goals set by the 1992 Act –
especially since the goals were substantially less than the share of these new mortgages in
the market.
To summarize: the academic and scientific literature has generally found little
effect from housing goals as they operated through the GSEs. The goals were low.
Despite appearances, they provided no incentive for the GSEs to “lead the market” in
providing credit to potentially riskier housing investments. They accomplished nothing in
increasing credit for riskier loans.
33
But there is a view that the housing goals were actively harmful in facilitating the
subprime housing crisis.
This position has been put most forcefully by Peter Wallison (2011) in his rebuttal
statement to the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission. He argues that the requirement to
meet the housing goals “forced” the GSEs to make substandard loans, which is why they
ultimately acquired such large positions in subprime mortgages and subprime mortgage
securities. Indeed, Wallison claims that the HUD goals actually “caused” the subprime
crisis. There is no question that the GSEs ultimately acquired large portfolios of subprime
mortgages and securities -- see our discussion in Section IV.A.4 above -- but Wallison
provides no evidence at all that these subprime portfolios had anything to do with the
GSE goals.
However, an impressive journalistic account of recent history in the mortgage
market argues forcefully that the housing goals in the 1992 act led directly to the
subprime mortgage debacle of 2008 (Morgenson and Rossner, 2011). Our analysis of the
academic literature supports no such claim. It is certainly possible that the passionate
rhetoric from the GSEs provided a convenient “cover” for the trend towards lower
quality, even toxic, mortgages by 2004-2005. However, there is no evidence that this
rhetoric increased GSE lending to targeted groups during the 1990s. Ironically (or
perhaps diabolically), the rhetoric about “affordable housing” from the GSEs had little
effect upon their own mortgage purchases until the subprime crisis was well underway.
As noted above, the empirical evidence simply fails to support a claim that the
GSE housing goals were a primary source of the subprime crisis. First, there are simple
questions of timing. The GSE goals were enunciated in a law passed in 1992; it is
34
implausible that their effect was not felt until a quarter century had elapsed. Further, as
noted below, the GSE accumulation of subprime mortgages accelerated only in 2007, too
late to have “caused’ the subprime bubble (but certainly early enough to have accelerated
it).
Second, as noted above, it appears that the GSE mortgage purchases in support of
the housing goals were principally loans that would otherwise have been made by other
lenders.
Most importantly, the subprime crisis has a long list of proximate causes,
including U.S. monetary policy, a global savings glut, the error of assuming a national
housing pricing collapse was highly unlikely, etc. (see Jaffee, 2009 for further
discussion.)
b. Benefits to all housing market participants
There has been active research seeking to establish the value of the enhanced
liquidity and subsidy to homeowners. In principle, the subsidy provided by the implicit
guarantee can be calculated. Freddie Mac and Fannie Mae issue debt in the same market
as other participants in the banking and finance industry participate. The yield difference
(“spread”) between the debt of the GSEs and that of other firms can be applied to the
newly issued GSE debt to compute the funding advantage in any year arising from the
GSE status. Of course, it is not quite straightforward to apply this principle and to
produce credible estimates. The relevant benchmark estimate (i.e., the appropriate sector
and bond rating) is not without controversy, and a comparison with broad aggregate
indices combines bonds containing a variety of embedded options. Pearce and Miller
(2001), among others, reported comparisons of GSE and AA-rated financial firms,
35
suggesting that the agencies enjoyed a 37 basis point (bps) spread. More sophisticated
comparisons by Nothaft, et al, (2002) suggest that the relative spreads are about 27 bps
(vis-à-vis AA-minus firms). Table 7 summarizes available comparisons. A careful
analysis of yields at issue for GSE debt and the option-free debt issued by a selection of
finance industry corporations (Ambrose and Warga, 2002) concludes that the GSEs enjoy
a spread of 25-29 bps over AA bank bonds and 37-46 over AA financials. Quigley (2006)
provides a terse summary of available estimates.
18
The substantial subsidies arising from the funding advantage of the GSEs means
that mortgage rates for all homeowners can be lower than they otherwise would be, that
is, the subsidy can improve the well-being of homeowners and home purchasers.
But of course, in the first instance the subsidy is provided directly to private
profit-making firms with fiduciary duties to their shareholders. It is thus not obvious that
all, or even most, of the funding advantage provided by the public subsidy is passed
through to homeowners. As documented by Hermalin and Jaffee (1996), the secondary
market for mortgage securities (at least for those securities composed of loans
comparable to the rules under which Fannie and Freddie operate) is hardly a textbook
model of atomistic competition. The two GSEs are large, and each has a large market
share of the conforming segment of the market. There are high barriers to entry, and the
MBS product is more-or-less homogeneous. Moreover, mortgage originators have an
inherent first-mover advantage in deciding which newly-issued mortgages to sell to
Fannie and Freddie. This may force the GSEs to pay a premium for the mortgages they
18
These estimates are in the range of the spreads which have been assumed (41 bps) by the Congressional
Budget Office (CBO, 2001) in estimating the annual federal subsidy to the GSEs. They are similar to the
estimates of spreads (40 bps) used by Passmore, (2005) in a more recent exercise.
36
purchase in the market. These factors, duopoly and adverse selection, may mean that
much of the subsidy accrues to the shareholders of the GSEs or to the owners of other
financial institutions, not to homeowners or home purchasers.
The effects of the GSEs upon mortgage rates can be calculated by estimating the
spread between the interest rates on mortgages which conform to the loan limits and
underwriting guidelines of the GSEs and the rates on otherwise comparable mortgages.
As in the analysis of funding advantages, it is not quite straightforward to apply this
principle and to produce credible estimates. (For example, most research compares the
rates paid by borrowers with loans one dollar below the conforming limit with rates paid
by borrowers with loans one dollar above the limit. But the latter group of borrowers
differs from the former group, or else they surely would have made an additional cash
payment and taken a conforming loan.)
19
Early analyses, e.g. by Hendershott and Shilling (1989) comparing interest rates
on jumbo and conforming mortgages, indicated that this spread was 24-39 bps. More
recent studies, e.g., by Passmore, et al (2002), by McKenzie (2002), and by the CBO
(2001), conclude that the spread is 18-23 bps. These more recent studies differ mostly in
their application of more complex screens to insure comparable data for conforming and
nonconforming loans. Table 8 summarizes these comparisons. More recent work by
Passmore, et al (2005) suggests that this spread may be as low as 16 bps.
19
Of course, other reasons besides the greater liquidity provided by the GSEs could explain some of an
observed spread between jumbo and conforming mortgages. Jumbo mortgages are generally prepaid more
aggressively -- borrowers have more at stake, if nothing else. This means that investors will require higher
rates on jumbos merely to compensate for the increased prepayment risk. On the other hand, borrowers
with jumbo mortgages have better credit, and they make larger down payments, which should create lower
rates on jumbo mortgages. See, also, Ambrose, et al (2001), Heuson, et al (2001), or Woodward (2004b).
37
In summary, it appears that the GSEs’ funding advantage is about 30-40 bps, and
the effect of this is to reduce mortgage rates by 16-25 bps. Stated another way, on the
order of half of the subsidy rate to the GSEs is transmitted to homeowners in the form of
reduced mortgage interest rates. Presumably, the remainder is transmitted to the
managers of the GSEs, the shareholders of the enterprises or to the owners of other
financial institutions.
20
VI. Where Do We Go From Here?
As noted in the introduction, most commentators agree that the current structure
of the housing finance system must be reformed in the very near term. A question of first-
order importance is then the likely consequences of the role of government in support of
the U.S. housing and mortgage markets, whether as a modification or replacement of the
GSEs.
The research results reported in this paper make it clear, we think, that the public
benefits arising from the GSEs have been quite small. The establishment of Fannie Mae,
a half century ago, and the establishment of Freddie Mac, forty years ago, did stimulate a
more stable national market for housing finance and did substantially improve the
liquidity and access of the market. As reported above, however, the specific benefits
arising from the GSE structure have been minor. In any event, these benefits -- with some
contributions from the GSEs -- were achieved by the 1980s. There now exists a national
market for home mortgages. The GSEs have followed reform in the secondary market
and have benefited from private innovation.
20
Of course, the net effects of the GSEs upon public welfare and the economy has greatly exceed the three
effects upon housing market participants discussed here. Indeed, the evidence suggests that the macro
economic effects of the structure and operation of the GSEs during the past half decade has been much
more important for the economy than the direct housing-market effects of the institutions.
38
There have been surprisingly few benefits to deserving households or
neighborhoods which can be attributed to the GSEs. There has been more political or
partisan attention to the cause of homeownership among lower-income households as a
result of powerful advocacy by the interests of GSEs, but there is little evidence that
lower-income homeownership was stimulated at all, at least not until the run up to the
housing bubble.
It is true that the GSE structure has reduced interest rates on home mortgages, by
about a quarter percent or so. But this benefit to homeowners has arisen from the federal
guarantee for GSE debt. And the public cost of the subsidy has been far more than the
benefits of lower interest rates to homeowners. About half of the overall subsidy has
accrued to GSE employees, shareholders, and other market intermediaries. These large
losses are directly attributable to the GSE structure which was created in 1968.
As noted below, we also conclude that the structure of the GSEs themselves has
made regulation of the housing market far less transparent and has extended some of the
consequences of the housing bubble of the past half decade.
A. The Appropriate Role for Government in the U.S. Residential Mortgage
Market
If the GSEs in current form are to be closed, the fundamental policy question is to
decide which government interventions, if any, should replace GSE functions and which
should be performed by the private sector? Once that is decided, there is also the delicate
issue of how to manage the transition from the current GSE conservatorship. Fortunately,
there are two quite flexible instruments available to close down the GSEs in a smooth,
safe and dependable manner: (i) steadily reduce the conforming loan limit until it reaches
39
zero; and (ii) steadily raise the fee charged by the GSEs for guaranteeing MBS. Although
we will return to questions of the dynamic transition below, the key question is to
determine the appropriate role of government in the U.S. mortgage market.
A large number of proposals have been offered for the reform of the U.S.
mortgage market, ranging from a mortgage market managed primarily by private sector
entities to recreation of the GSEs as public/private hybrids (albeit with new controls).
Summaries and analyses of the general approaches are available in U.S. General
Accountability Office (2009), Congressional Budget Office (2010), and Bernanke (2008).
The following is an annotated list of the three primary proposals scrutinized:
Reestablish GSEs with tighter controls and explicit guarantees. The entities would
continue their organization as public/private hybrids, but with tight government
controls, sometimes described as a “public utility” model. In most plans, the
government guarantees would apply to the underlying mortgages, not the newly
created entities. A cooperative structure such as that of the current Federal Home
Loan Banks is an alternative version. The number of entities to be chartered varies by
proposal.
Restructure GSE functions explicitly within a government agency
. A simple version
would create a government agency that would explicitly insure mortgages up to some
conforming limit and then securitize pools of these mortgages, very much as the
current FHA and GNMA agencies operate. The support for underserved borrowers
and areas, including multi-family housing, currently covered under the GSE housing
goals, would then continue in a revised form as explicit government programs.
40
Privatization of the U.S. mortgage market. This proposal would create a fully
privatized mortgage market, with no special federal backing for the secondary
mortgage market, although this could include spinning out the GSEs as new private
entities.
More recently, in February 2011, the U.S. Treasury and Housing and Urban
Development agency, U.S. Treasury/HUD 2011), issued a white paper that offered an
alternative list of three policy options. The policy options were based on three principles
(White paper, p. 11):
1. Pave the way for a robust private mortgage market by reducing government support for
housing finance and closing down Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac on a responsible
timeline;
2. Address fundamental flaws in the mortgage market to protect borrowers, to help ensure
transparency for investors, and to increase the role of private capital;
3. Target the government's vital support for affordable housing in a “more effective and
transparent manner.”
In effect, these principles rule out the reestablishment of the GSEs as
private/public hybrids.
The White paper then offers three options for long-term mortgage market reform:
Option 1
: A privatized system of housing finance with the government insurance role
limited to FHA, USDA and Department of Veterans’ Affairs’ assistance for narrowly
targeted groups of borrowers.
41
Option 2: A privatized system of housing finance with assistance from FHA, USDA and
the VA for narrowly targeted groups of borrowers and a guarantee mechanism to scale up
during times of crisis.
Option 3: A privatized system of housing finance with FHA, USDA and the VA
assistance for low- and moderate-income borrowers and catastrophic reinsurance behind
significant private capital.
Since the publication of the White paper, most discussions of specific proposals
among academics, public interest groups, and market participants have centered on
versions of the “Option 3.” The alternative views expressed in these discussions mainly
concern the extent and form in which the government’s mortgage guarantees would be
provided. Of course, if the government guarantee is sufficiently limited, “option 3” is no
different from “option 2.” While these discussions have focused on the form of the
government mortgage guarantee, most commentators agree that the abusive mortgage
market practices that evolved during the subprime boom must be ended through
regulation; see U.S. Treasury/HUD (2011, pp.15-18). In fact, Federal Reserve (2008)
actions to modify the Truth in Lending Act and a wide range of requirements in the
Dodd-Frank Act have already gone a long way to eliminating any possible replay of such
abusive practices in the U.S. mortgage market. Most commentators also appear to agree
that the GSE housing goals should be replaced with an explicit and transparent system of
targeted support for access and affordability. An obvious solution, and one endorsed by
the White Paper, is to strengthen and expand the FHA for this purpose. The White Paper
also proposes a public commitment to affordable rental housing.
42
B. Government Insurance of U.S. Mortgages
We now review the major issues and differences among the plans that are
proposed as the mechanism to replace the GSEs with a program of federal government
mortgage insurance. Specific versions are available from Acharya, Richardson Van
Nieuwerburgh, and White (2011), the Center for American Progress (2010), Ellen, Tye,
and Willis (2010), and Hancock and Passmore (2010). While the plans differ in details
and specificity, a composite can be summarized:
1) The plans anticipate government regulations will set the underwriting standards to be
met by all mortgages that underlie the qualifying MBS, roughly comparable to the
standards historically applied by the GSEs. The plans also generally anticipate a size limit
roughly equivalent to the conforming loan limit historically applied to the GSEs;
2) Investors in the qualifying MBS will be protected from all default risk by a
combination of private capital and government guarantee. The government guarantee
component is considered essential. The various plans differ primarily in the split between
private capital and government guarantee;
3) Risk-based insurance premia will be paid to the private capital and the government as
compensation for the risks they bear.
For simplicity, we refer to this structure as the “government insurance proposal.”
A key feature of the insurance proposal relative to any plan that would recreate the GSEs
is that the government would set the underwriting standards and be compensated for the
risk it bears.
The immediate question is whether the government can be effective and efficient
in carrying out such a mortgage insurance program. Evidence is available from a variety
43
of existing government insurance programs. Perhaps the most positive evidence is the
FHA program itself. As noted earlier, this program has existed since 1934, sets its
premiums on an actuarial basis, and has never required a government subsidy or bailout
for its self-supporting programs. Most interestingly, as documented in Jaffee and Quigley
(2010), the FHA effectively sat out the subprime boom, allowing its overall market share
to fall from a peak share of twenty-five percent in 1970 to under two percent by 2006.
Even more dramatically, its market share of loans to minority borrowers, which had been
close to fifty percent of this market as recently as 2000, fell to well below ten percent by
2006. In effect, the FHA took no action to deter its traditional clients from switching to
private market lenders and the GSEs as the source of their mortgage loans. While this
inaction could not protect the FHA from the rising loss rate that is now affecting most
segments of the U.S. mortgage market, it has certainly minimized the dollar amount of
the losses that the FHA could still potentially impose on U.S. taxpayers.
The FHA thus provides a model, or even a precise mechanism, for a broad
government guarantee program, possibly covering the same market share—at times fifty
percent of the overall market—that was traditionally served by the GSEs. Indeed,
operating within its traditional programs, the FHA market share of total mortgage
originations has already jumped dramatically from under two percent in 2006 to over
twenty percent in 2010. The issue is whether the FHA mechanism, which has worked
well serving a well-defined set of lower-income clients, can scale efficiently to serve
what could be as much as three quarters of the entire U.S. mortgage market (summing a
50 percent GSE share with a traditional 25 percent FHA share). The major concern is
whether the FHA -- or any comparable government insurance plan -- can resist the
44
political pressures to reduce its underwriting standards and to subsidize its risk-based
insurance premiums. The evidence here is not encouraging.
An interesting and comparable case is the National Flood Insurance Program
(NFIP). The NFIP was created in 1968, following a series of disastrous mid-western
floods that caused a large part of the private insurance industry to stop offering flood
coverage. The NFIP legislation required premiums to be set on an actuarial basis,
including risk-based premiums, to discourage the construction of new homes in flood
zones. This noble goal floundered, however, when the owners of existing properties in
dangerous flood plains successfully lobbied to obtain special “grandfathered” premium
reductions. This all become evident when there were insufficient reserves to pay the
losses created by Hurricane Katrina, thus requiring taxpayer bailout of the NFIP on the
order of $22 billion. Further discussion of the NFIP see Michel-Kerjan and Kunreuther
(2011) and of failed government insurance programs in general see Jaffee and Russell
(2006).
The Terrorism Risk Insurance Act (TRIA) provides an alternative approach to
government insurance and may provide a useful structure for a government mortgage
insurance program. TRIA was first passed by Congress in 2002, following the terrorism
attack of September 2001. The issue was that, as a result of their World Trade Center
losses, virtually all property insurers were refusing to renew policies on large commercial
buildings unless there was a substantial government reinsurance program to cap their
potential losses. TRIA accomplished this goal with a structure in which the government
provides the insurers protection against possible catastrophic losses while placing the
insurers in the first-loss position with a series of deductibles and coinsurance
45
requirements. Roughly speaking, TRIA 2002 required the industry itself to cover most of
the losses that would have resulted from another event comparable to the sabotage of
2011, but provided quite complete government protection against any losses above that
level. TRIA has now been renewed two times, and both times the deductible and
coinsurance requirements have been raised, so a taxpayer loss would now occur only with
truly extreme events.
21
The specific proposals offered by Acharya, Richardson, Van Nieuwerburgh, and
White (2011) and Hancock and Passmore (2010) both reference “catastrophe insurance”
as the coverage to be provided under their plans. A particular concern, however, is that
MBS investors might not consider government catastrophe coverage to be a sufficient
inducement for them to take the first-loss positions on portfolios of U.S. mortgages. For
example, while the property insurers may have been most concerned with the last twenty
percent of the tail risk from terrorist attacks, investors in residential mortgage pools may
be primarily concerned with the first twenty percent of the risk distribution. In that case,
for a government mortgage insurance program to be effective, it may have to mimic the
NFIP more than TRIA. In other words, even if the starting point were the principle of a
backstop to catastrophe, the political process may create a plan that covers high-risk
mortgages at subsidized rates, i.e., GSEs with a different “cover.”
This appears to be the conundrum for creating a feasible program for government
insurance of U.S. mortgages. While a true catastrophe government insurance plan appears
feasible, investors and other market participants will, of course, have incentives to push
as much of the first-loss risk as possible under the government’s coverage. If the political
21
On the other hand, the government’s TRIA coverage is provided without charge.
46
process can stand firm on the issue, then it is quite possible that private incentives will
create an efficient market for U.S. mortgages. After all, it is hard to believe that only the
countries of Western Europe have the ability to create effective mortgage markets while
maintaining a low level of government intervention.
C. The Role of GSE Mortgage Market Activity under the Conservatorship
In concluding, it is relevant to comment on the role of GSE mortgage market
activity since the two firms were placed under a government Conservatorship in
September 2008. Relevant data on the home mortgage acquisitions of the GSEs and for
the total home mortgage market are shown in Table 9 for 2009 and 2010. The raw
numbers suggest a significant GSE and overall government role. For 2009 and 2010,
annual GSE mortgage acquisitions as a percentage of total home originations was 63
percent. FHA and VA activity averaged 24 percent of total home originations over the
same period, so government programs participated in 87 percent of all mortgage
originations for 2009 and 2010.
The high GSE market share under the Conservatorship, however, can be
misleading. First, 80 percent of all GSE mortgage acquisitions were refinanced loans, so
only 20 percent of the GSE activity represented loans for home purchase. The GSE
refinancing activity includes the refinancings that occurred under the Home Affordable
Refinance Program (HARP). In comparison, for the overall mortgage market, home
refinancings represented 68 percent of total mortgage originations, leaving 32% of the
originations for home purchase activity. The conclusion is that while the GSEs dominated
U.S. mortgage market activity in 2009 and 2010, most of this activity was simply the
refinancing of mortgage loans that had already been guaranteed by the GSEs. To be clear,
47
refinancing activities are certainly beneficial to the borrowers, and generally so for the
GSEs as well (since they reduce the likelihood of default on these loans for which the
GSEs are already at risk). On the other hand, refinancing is a zero-sum game, since the
investors who are holding the higher rate mortgages will have to reinvest their money at
the now lower market rates. Indeed, the Federal Reserve, U.S. Treasury, and GSEs are
major holders of these GSE mortgage securities, so the HARP program is far from cost-
free for the government itself.
22
The GSEs also participate in the Home Affordable Modification Program
(HAMP), along with servicers for non-GSE home mortgages. As of September 2011, the
GSE share of total HAMP modifications was 52 percent, only slightly above the GSE
share of all outstanding home mortgages. This suggests that the participation rate in
HAMP modifications was about the same for GSE and non-GSE mortgages. Perhaps
more importantly, the HAMP program is widely considered to be a disappointment: as of
September 2011, just over 800 thousand loans had been modified, compared to the earlier
hopes of 3 to 4 million loans.
The overall conclusion is that the primary mortgage market result of maintaining
the GSEs under the government Conservatorship through 2011 appears to have been their
role as a catalyst for the refinancing of their existing mortgages. In terms of funding for
home purchase loans, private market lenders have actually been more active than the
GSEs, even without the benefit of a government guarantee.
22
See Remy, Lucas, and Moore (2011) for a Congressional Budget Office analysis of the most recent
changes in the HARP program.
48
Data Appendix
The Federal Reserve Flow of Funds (FoF) tables provide the longest (1945 to the
present), consistent, quantification of home mortgages outstanding.
23
The FoF data
include a separation between mortgages held directly in investor portfolios and those held
within mortgage pools for mortgage-backed securitization (MBS), including some detail
on the holders of each category. For Tables 1 and 2 and Figures 1 and 2, we apply the
FoF data for the aggregate outstanding home mortgages and the separation between loans
held in portfolios and in mortgage pools.
For the separation of MBS outstanding among three issuer classes, the FoF data
directly quantify MBS issued by private label securitizers (PLS, meaning MBS without
government or GSE backing), and the sum of GNMA and GSE data. We obtain direct
measures of GNMA MBS outstanding from the Historical Statistics of the United States
(with the latest 2010 data from Inside ABS), and compute the GSE MBS outstanding as
the residual, (which closely aligns with direct measures of GSE MBS from the
company’s own reports).
24
For the separation of whole mortgages and MBS among three holder classes, the
FoF data directly quantify the whole home mortgages and the securitized pools held by
depository institutions (commercial banks, savings and loan associations, savings banks,
and credit unions). Whole mortgages and MBS held in the retained portfolios of the GSE
are obtained from the 2010 report to Congress their regulator, Federal Housing Finance
23
The FoF data are available at http://www.feder alreserve.gov/releases/z1/Current/data.htm . Home
mortgages are defined as mortgages on 1 to 4 family homes, thus excluding multifamily, farm, and
commercial mortgages.
24
Both GSEs adopted an accounting change—integrating their outstanding MBS commitments onto their
balance sheet—that makes their 2010 data inconsistent with all previous data. Our method avoids this
accounting change, allowing us to maintain consistency throughout the sample period.
49
Agency (2010), with the 2010 data obtained from the companies’ Monthly Volume
reports. Whole mortgages and MBS held by other investors are computed as the residual
category.
50
Bibliography
Aaronson, D. (2000). “A note on the benefit of homeownership,” Journal of Urban
Economics, 47, 356-369.
Acharya, Viral, Matthew Richardson, Stijn Van Nieuwerburgh, and Lawrence J. White
(2011), Guaranteed to Fail, Princeton University Press.
Ambrose, Brent W, Richard Buttimer, Thomas Thibodeau (2001), “A New Spin on the
Jumbo/Conforming Loan Rate Differential.” Journal of Real Estate Finance and
Economics, November 2001, 23(3), pp. 309-35.
Ambrose, B. W., and Thibodeau, T. G. (2004). “Have the GSE affordable housing goals
increased the supply of mortgage credit?” Regional Science and Urban
Economics, 34, 263-272.
An, X., and Bostic, R. W. (2006, April 28). Have the Affordable Housing Goals been a
Shield against Subprime? Regulatory Incentives and the Extension of Mortgage
Credit. Retrieved from
http://www.usc.edu/schools/sppd/lusk/research/pdf/wp_2006-1006.pdf
An, X., and Bostic, R. W. (2008). “GSE Activity, FHA Feedback, and Implications for
the Efficacy of the Affordable Housing Goals,” Journal of Real Estate Finance
Economics, 36, 207-231.
An, X., and Bostic, R. W. (2009). “Policy Incentives and the Extension of Mortgage
Credit: Increasing Market Discipline for Subprime Lending,” Journal of Policy
Analysis and Management, 28 (3), 340-365.
An, X., Bostic, R. W., Deng, Y., Gabriel, S. A., Green, R. K., and Tracy, J. (2007). “GSE
Loan Purchases, the FHA, and Housing Outcomes in Targeted, Low-Income
Neighborhoods,” Brookings Institution Press, 205-256.
Avery, R. B., and Brevoort, K. P. (2010, August). The Subprime Crisis: How Much Did
Lender Regulation Matter? Retrieved June 2, 2011, from
http://business.gwu.edu/creua/research-papers/files/subprime-crisis.pdf
Avery, R., Bostic, R., and Canner, G. (2005). “Assessing the Necessity and Efficiency of
the Community Reinvestment Act,” Housing Policy Debate, 16 (1), 143-172.
Brevoort, Kenneth and Robert Avery (2011), “The Subprime Crisis: Is Government
Housing Policy to Blame? (with Robert B. Avery), Finance and Economics
Discussion Series 2011-36. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System.
51
Bernanke, Ben (2008), “The Future of Mortgage Finance in the United States,” speech at
the UC Berkeley/UCLA Symposium: The Mortgage Meltdown, the Economy,
and Public Policy, Berkeley California, October 31, 2008; available at:
http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20081031a.htm
Bhutta, N. (2009a, March). GSE Activity and Mortgage Supply in Lower-Income and
Minority Neighborhoods: The Effect of the Affordable Housing Goals. Retrieved
from
http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/2009/200903/revision/200903pap.pdf
Bhutta, N. (2009b, March). Regression Discontinuity Estimates of the Effects of the GSE
Act of 1992. Retrieved June 2, 2011, from
http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/2009/200903/200903pap.pdf
Bhutta, N. (2010, February 5). The Community Reinvestment Act and Mortgage Lending
to Lower Income Borrowers and Neighborhoods. Retrieved from
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1694762
Bostic, R. W., and Gabriel, S. A. (2006). “Do the GSEs matter to low-income housing
markets? An assessment of the effects of the GSE loan purchase goals on
California housing outcomes,” Journal of Urban Economics, 59, 458-475.
Boyle, M. H. (2002). Home Ownership and the Emotional and Behavioral Problems of
Children and Youth. Child Development, 73 (3), 883-892.
Bubb, Ryan and Alex Kaufman (2009), “Securitization and Moral Hazard: Evidence
from a Lender Cutoff Rule, Public Policy Discussion Paper No. 09-5, Federal
Reserve Bank of Boston.
Burnett, K., and Fosburg, L. B. (2001, August). Retrieved May 27, 2011, from
http://www.huduser.org/Publications/pdf/gsemultifamily.pdf
Canner, Glenn, Wayne Passmore, and Brian Surette (1996), “Distribution of Credit Risk
among Providers of Mortgages to Lower-Income and Minority Homebuyers,”
Federal Reserve Bulletin, December 1996.
Center for American Progress (2010), A Responsible Secondary Market System for
Housing Finance,” available at:
http://www.americanprogress.org/issues/2010/09/pdf/housing_finance_slides.pdf
Chirui, Maria Conceeta and Tullio Jappelli, “Financial Market Imperfections and Home
Ownership: A Comparative Study,” European Economic Review, 47, pp. 857-75.
Coales, Adrian and Judith Hardt (2000), “Mortgage Markets: Why US and EU Markets
are So Different,” Housing Studies, Vol. 15, No. 5, 775-83.
Congressional Budget Office (1996), “Assessing the Public Costs and Benefits of Fannie
Mae and Freddie Mac,” May 1996.
52
Congressional Budget Office (2001), “Federal Subsidies and the Housing GSEs,”
Washington, DC: GPO, 2001
Congressional Budget Office (2010), “Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and the Federal Role in
the Secondary Mortgage Market,” December 2010.
Conley, D., and Gifford, B. (2006). Home Ownership, Social Insurance, and the Welfare
State. Springer, 21 (1), 55-82.
Coulson, E., and Li, H. (2010, September). Measuring the External Benefits of
Homeownership. Retrieved from http://erwan.marginalq.com/HULM11s/ec.pdfde
Tocqueville, Alexis (1835), Democracy in America.
Dietz, R. D., and Haurin, D. R. (2003). “The Social and Private Micro-Level
Consequences of Homeownership,” Journal of Urban Economics, 54, 401-450.
DiPasquale, D., and Glaeser, E. L. (1999). “Incentives and Social Capital: Are
Homeowners Better Citizens?” Journal of Urban Economics, 45, 354-384.
Ellen, Ingrid Gould, John Napier Tye, and Mark A. Willis (2010), “Improving U.S.
Housing Finance through Reform of Fannie and Freddie Mac, Furman Center for
Real Estate and Urban Policy, New York University, available at:
http://furmancenter.org/files/publications/Improving_US_Housing_Finance_Fann
ie_Mae_Freddie_Mac_9_8_10.pdf
European Central Bank (2009), “Housing Finance in the Euro Area,” Occasional Paper
Series No. 101, March 2009.
European Mortgage Federation (2009), Hypotstat 2009, available at:
http://hypo.org/Content/default.asp?PageID=524
Federal Housing Finance Agency (2010a), “Data on the Risk Characteristics of Single-
Family Mortgages Originated from 2001 through 2008 and Financed in the
Secondary Market, September 13, 2010, available at:
http://www.fhfa.gov/webfiles/16711/RiskChars9132010.pdf
Federal Housing Finance Agency (2010b), Report to Congress 2010, June 13, 2011.
Federal Housing Finance Agency (2011), “Conservator’s Report on the Enterprises’
Financial Performance, Second Quarter 2011,” available at:
http://www.fhfa.gov/webfiles/22615/ConservatorsReport2Q2011.pdfFederal
Housing Finance Agency. (2009). Retrieved from Report to Congress 2009,
Historical Data Tables:
http://www.fhfa.gov/webfiles/15784/FHFAReportToCongress52510.pdf
53
Federal Housing Finance Agency. (n.d.). FHFA Sends GSE Housing Goals to Federal
Register Proposed Rule Adjusts Certain Goals for Market Conditions; Provides
Credit for Loan Modifications. Retrieved May 25, 2011, from
http://www.fhfa.gov/webfiles/2139/
Federal Reserve (2008), “Highlights of Final Rule Amending Home Mortgage Provisions
of Regulation Z (Truth in Lending),” release of July 14, 2008, available at:
http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/bcreg/regz20080714.htm
Frame, Scott and Lawrence White (2005), “Fussing and Fuming Over Fannie and
Freddie: How Much Smoke, How Much Fire?” Journal of Economic
Perspectives, Vol. 19, No. 2, Pp. 159-184, Spring 2005.
Friedman, S., and Squires, G. D. (2005). Does the Community Reinvestment Act Help
Minorities Access Traditionally Inaccessible Neighborhoods? University of
California Press, 52 (2), 209-231.
Gabriel, S. A., and Rosenthal, S. S. (2010). “Do the GSEs Expand the Supply of
Mortgage Credit? New Evidence of Crowd Out in the Secondary Mortgage
Market,” Journal of Public Economics, 94, 975-986.
Glaeser, Edward and Dwight Jaffee (2006), “What to Do About Fannie and Freddie,”
Economists’ Voice, available at: www.bepress/ev, September 2006.
Green, Richard (2011), “Testimony,” Senate Banking Committee, available at:
http://banking.senate.gov/public/index.cfm?FuseAction=Hearings.Hearing&Heari
ng_ID=a7b4b965-7291-4741-8507-f1dbbb860ac0
Green, R. K., and Hendershott, P. H. (2001). “Homeownership and Unemployment in the
US,” Journal of Urban Studies, 38 (9), 1509-1520.
Green, R. K., and White, M. J. (1997). “Measuring the Benefits of Homeowning: Effects
on Children,” Journal of Urban Economics, 41, 441-461.
Guttentag, J. Federal National Mortgage Association, Federal Credit Agencies.
Washington DC, Commission on Money and Credit, by Prentice Hall 1963.
Hancock, Diana and Wayne Passmore (2010), “An Analysis of Government Guarantees
and the Functioning of Asset-Backed Securities Markets,” Finance and
Economics Discussion Series No. 2010-46, Federal Reserve Board.
Haurin, D. R., Dietz, R. D., and Weinberg, B. A. (2002, March 6). The Impact of
Neighborhood Homeownership Rates: A Review of the Theoretical and Empirical
Literature. Retrieved from
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=303398
Haurin, D. R., Parcel, T. L., and Huarin, R. J. (2002). “Does Homeownership Affect
Child Outcomes?” Real Estate Economics, 30 (4), 635-666.
54
Hendershott, Patrick H. and James Shilling (1989(, “The Impact of the Agencies on
Conventional Fixed-Rate Mortgage Yields.” Journal of Real Estate Finance and
Economics, June 1989, 2(2), pp. 101-15.
Herbert, C. E. (2001, August). An Assessment of the Availability and Cost of Financing
for Small Multifamily Properties. Retrieved May 27, 2011, from
http://www.huduser.org/publications/pdf/smallmultifamily.pdf
Hermalin, Benjamin and Dwight Jaffee (1996),. “The Privatization of Fannie Mae and
Freddie Mac: Implications for Mortgage Industry Structure,” in Studies on
Privatizing Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, Washington, DC: HUD, pp. 225-302.
Heuson, Andrea, Wayne Passmore and Roger Sparks (2001), “Credit Scoring and
Mortgage Securitization: Implications for Mortgage Rates and Credit
Availability.” Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, November 2001,
23(3), pp. 337-64.
Jaffee, Dwight (2009) “The U.S. Subprime Mortgage Crisis: Issues Raised and Lessons
Learned,” Chapter 7 in Michael Spence, Patricia Clarke Annez and Robert M.
Buckley, editors, Urbanization and Growth, World Bank, 2009, available online
at
http://www.growthcommission.org/storage/cgdev/documents/ebookurbanization.p
df
Jaffee, Dwight (2010a), “The Role of the GSEs and Housing Policy in the Financial
Crisis,” Testimony before the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission, February 25,
2010, available at: http://fcic.law.stanford.edu/hearings/testimony/forum-to-
explore-the-causes-of-the-financial-crisis
Jaffee, Dwight (2010b), “How to Privatize the Mortgage Market,” Wall Street Journal,
October 25, 2010.
Jaffee, Dwight (2011) ““Testimony,” Senate Banking Committee, available at:
http://banking.senate.gov/public/index.cfm?FuseAction=Hearings.Hearing&Heari
ng_ID=a7b4b965-7291-4741-8507-f1dbbb860ac0
Jaffee, Dwight and John Quigley (2007), “Housing Subsidies and Homeowners: What
Role for Government-Sponsored Enterprises?” Brookings Papers.
Jaffee, Dwight and John Quigley (2010), “Housing Policy, Mortgage Policy, and the
Federal Housing Administration,” in Deborah Lucas editor, Measuring and
Managing Financial Risk, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Jaffee, Dwight and Kenneth Rosen (1978), “Estimates of the Effectiveness of
Stabilization Policies for the Mortgage and Housing Markets," with K. Rosen,
Journal of Finance XXXIII, No. 3 (1978), 933-946.
55
Jaffee, Dwight and Kenneth Rosen (1979), “Mortgage Credit Availability and Residential
Construction,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 1979, No. 2, pp.
333-386. Jaffee, Dwight and Kenneth Rosen (1978)
Jaffee, Dwight and Thomas Russell (2006), “Should Governments Provide Catastrophe
Insurance?”, The Economists' Voice: Vol. 3 : Iss. 5, Article 6, available at:
http://www.bepress.com/ev/vol3/iss5/art6
Keys, Benjamin J., Tanmoy Mukherjee, Amit Seru, and Vikrant Vig (2010), “Did
Securitization Lead to Lax Screening? Evidence from Subprime Loans,” The
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125(1): 307-362.
Laderman, Elizabeth and Carolina Reid (2008), “Lending in Low- and Moderate- Income
Neighborhoods in California: The Performance of CREA Lending During the
Subprime Meltdown, Community Development Working Paper 2008-05,
November 2008.
Lea, Michael (2010), International Comparison of Mortgage Product Offerings, Research
Institute for Housing America, September 2010.
Lehnert, Andreas, Wayne Passmore, and Shane Sherlund, “GSEs, Mortgage Rates, and
Secondary Market Activities,” The Journal of Real Estate Finance and
Economics, Volume 36, Number 3, pp. 343-363.
Lehnert, Andreas, Wayne Passmore, and Shane Sherlund, “GSEs, Mortgage Rates, and
Secondary Market Activities (2008),” The Journal of Real Estate Finance and
Economics, “ Vol. 36, No. 3, pp. 343-361.
Lewis, Michael, Liars Poker, (1990), New York, Penguin.
Manchester, Paul (2007), “Goal Performance and Characteristics of Mortgages Purchased
by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, 2001-2005, HUD Housing Finance Working
Paper HF-17.
Marcus, C. E. (1996). “Beyond the Boundaries of the Community Reinvestment Act and
the Fair Lending Laws: Developing a Market-Based Framework for Generating
Low- and Moderate-Income Lending,” Columbia Law Review, 710-758.
McKenzie, Joseph A. (2002) “A Reconsideration of the Jumbo/Non-Jumbo Mortgage
Rate Differential,” Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, September-
December 2002, 25(2/3), pp. 197-214.
Michel-Kerjan, Erwann and Howard Kunreuther (2011), “Redesigning Flood Insurance,”
Science, Vol 333, pp. 408-409.
Morgenson, Gretch and Joshua Rosner (2011), Reckless Endangerment: How Outsized
Ambition, Greed, and Corruption Led to Economic Armageddon, Henry Holt and
Company.
56
Mortgage Bankers Association, Real Estate Finance Association. (2009, September).
Retrieved from
http://www.gbreb.com/uploadedFiles/REFA/Education_and_Events/Content_Blo
cks/Freddie%20Fannie%20and%20FHA%20Presentation%20Final2%281%29.pd
f?n=8957
Moulton, S. (n.d.). The 1992 GSE Act and Loan Application Outcomes. Retrieved from
http://research.stlouisfed.org/conferences/gse/Moulton.pdf
Moulton, Stephanie 2010), “Originating Lender Localness and Mortgage Sustainability,”
Public Administration Review, 70(3): 349-360.
Munch, J. R., Rosholm, M., and Svarer, M. (2008). “Home ownership, Job Duration, and
Wages,” Journal of Urban Economics, 68, 130-145.
Naranjo Andy and Alden Toevs (2002), “The Effects of Purchases of Mortgages and
Securitizations by Government Sponsored Enterprises on Mortgage Yield Spreads
and Volatility,” Fannie Mae Papers, 2002, Vol. 1, Issue 3, pp. 1-14.
Nothaft, Frank E, James Pearce, and Steven Stevanovic (2002), “Debt Spreads Between
GSEs and Other Corporations,” Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics,
September-December 2002, 25(2/3), pp. 151-72.
Oswald, A. (1996). A Conjecture on the Explanation for High Unemployment in the
Industrialized Nations: Part I. University of Warwick Working Paper No. 475.
Passmore, Wayne (2005) “The GSE Implicit Subsidy and the Value of Government
Ambiguity.” Real Estate Economics, Fall 2005, 33(3), pp. 465-86.
Passmore, Wayne, Roger Sparks, and Jamie Ingpen (2002),“GSEs, Mortgage Rates, and
the Long-Run Effects of Mortgage Securitization.” Journal of Real Estate
Finance and Economics, September-December 2002, 25(2/3), pp. 215-42.
Passmore, Wayne, Shane Sherlundand Burgess Gillian (2005), “The Effect of Housing
Government-Sponsored Enterprises on Mortgage Rates.” Real Estate Economics,
Fall 2005, 33(3), pp. 427-63.
Pearce, James E. and James Miller (2001), “Freddie Mac and Fannie Mae: Their Funding
Advantages and Benefits to Consumers,” Freddie Mac.
Peek, Joe and James A. Wilcox. “Secondary Mortgage Markets, GSEs, and the Changing
Cyclicality of Mortgage Flows,” ed. Andrew H. Chen, Research in Finance
Volume 20, pp. 61-80, 2003.
Quigley, J. M. (2006). “Federal Credit and Insurance Programs: Housing,” Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 281-310.
57
Quinn, Sarah (2010), Government Policy, Housing, and the Origins of Securitization,
1780-1968, Ph.D. Thesis, University of California, Berkeley, and forthcoming
Princeton University Press.
Report by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. (2000, July). Retrieved
June 2, 2011, from
http://www.federalreserve.gov/communitydev/files/cra_cratext.pdf
Rossi, P. H., and Weber, E. (1996). “The Social Benefits of Homeownership: Empirical
Evidence from National Surveys,” Housing Policy Debate, 7 (1).
Segal, W., and Szymanoski, E. J. (1998). Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and the Multifamily
Mortgage Market. Cityscape: A Journal of Policy Development and Research, 59-
91.
Thomas, Jason and Robert Van Order (2011), “A Closer Look at Fannie Mae and Freddie
Mac: What We Know, What We Think We Know and What We Don’t Know,
available at: http://business.gwu.edu/creua/research-papers/files/fannie-
freddie.pdf
U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development (1966), Background and History of
the Federal National Mortgage Association.
U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, O. o. (n.d.). Overview of the GSEs'
Housing Goal Performance, 1993-2001. Retrieved May 25, 2011, from
http://www.huduser.org/datasets/GSE/gse2001.pdf
U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, O. o. (n.d.). Overview of the GSEs'
Housing Performance, 2000-2007. Retrieved May 25, 2011, from
http://www.huduser.org/datasets/GSE/gse2007.pdf
U.S. Treasury and Housing and Urban Development (2011), “Reforming America’s
Housing Finance Market, A Report to Congress,” February, 2011
United States Government Accountability Office (2009), “Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac:
Analysis of Options for Revising the Housing Enterprises’ Long-term Structures,”
GAO-09-782, September 2009
.
Wallison, Peter (2011), “Dissent from the Majority Report of the Financial Crisis Inquiry
Commission, January 14, 2011, available at:
http://www.aei.org/docLib/Wallisondissent.pdf
Weicher, J. C. (2010). The Affordable Housing Goals, Homeownership and Risk: Some
Lessons from Past Efforts to Regulate the GSEs. The Past, Present, and Future of
the Government-Sponsored Enterprises (pp. 1-28). St Louis: Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis.
58
Woodward, Susan E. (2004a) “Recharting Freddie and Fannie: The Policy Issues.”
Unpublished manuscript.
Woodward, Susan E. (2004b) “Estimating the Jumbo Rate Premium with Clean and Rich
Loan Level Data.” Unpublished manuscript, Sand Hill Econometrics.
Wyly, E. K., and Holloway, S. R. (2002). The Disappearance of Race in Mortgage
Lending. Economic Geography, 78 (2), 129-169.
59
Table 1
Outstanding Whole Home Mortgages
Year
1950
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
A. Billions of Dollars
Portfolio Holdings $45 $141 $289 $851 $1,496 $2,297 $3,918
Depository Institutions 27 95 207 642 1,066 1,669 2,959
Market Investors 17 40 65 146 316 441 478
GSE Portfolios 1 6 17 62 114 187 481
Mortgage Pools 0 0 3 107 1,111 2,811 6,614
GSE Pools 0 0 0 13 652 1814 4,311
GNMA Pools 0 0 3 94 404 612 1,038
PLS Pools 0 0 0 0 55 386 1,265
Total $45 $141 $292 $958 $2,606 $5,108 $10,531
B. Percentage of Total
Portfolio Holdings 100% 100% 99% 89% 57% 45% 37%
Depository Institutions 60 67 71 67 41 33 28
Market Investors 38 29 22 15 12 5 5
GSE Portfolios 2 4 6 7 4 8 5
Mortgage Pools 0 0 1 11 43 55 63
GSE Pools 0 0 0 1 25 36 41
GNMA Pools 0 0 1 10 15 12 10
PLS Pools 0 0 0 0 2 8 12
Total 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100%
C. GSE Whole Loans Held
+ MBS Issued
3% 4% 6% 8% 29% 44% 46%
Source: see data appendix
60
Table 2
Holdings of Whole Home Mortgages and MBS by Investor Class
Billions of Dollars
1950
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
Depository Institutions
Whole Mortgages $27 $95 $207 $642 $1,066 $1,669 $2,959
MBS 0 0 0 41 385 604 1,368
Total 27 95 207 683 1,450 2,272 4,326
Market Investors
Whole Mortgages 17 40 65 146 316 195 478
MBS 0 0 3 66 714 1,446 4,444
Total 17 40 68 212 1,030 1,641 4,923
GSEs
Whole Mortgages 1 6 17 62 114 433 481
MBS 0 0 0 0 12 762 802
Total 1 6 17 62 126 1,195 1,283
Total Home Mortgages $45 $141 $292 $958 $2,606 $5,107 $10,531
Source: see data appendix
61
Table 3
Conforming Mortgage Originations by Origination Year,
Characteristics, and GSE Market Share
A. Conforming Originations,
25
Billions of Dollars
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007
(1) Loan to Value Ratio > 90% 108 121 154 130 112 115 169
(2) FICO Score < 620 94 126 164 194 211 162 92
(3) ARMs 83 200 332 516 579 447 165
(4) High Risk Originations
26
241 367 536 664 719 597 374
(5) Total Conforming Originations 1,064 1,451 2,074 1,331 1,454 1,307 1,117
(6) High Risk as % of Total Conforming 22.6% 25.3% 25.9% 49.9% 49.5% 45.7% 33.5%
B. GSE Share of Risk Attributes
(7) Loan to Value Ratio > 90% 92.2% 86.4% 76.0% 59.6% 58.4% 66.8% 93.1%
(8) FICO Score < 620 63.9 56.7 47.0 25.1 22.4 32.5 76.8
(9) ARMs 50.7 60.5 56.5 36.8 29.0 33.1 62.6
(10) High Risk Originations 77.2 72.7 65.3 43.5 36.3 42.5 79.9
(11) GSE Share Total Conforming Loans 93.7 91.6 88.7 67.5 61.9 67.1 90.7
C. Relative Intensity (1.0 = “Market Portfolio”)
27
(12) Loan to Value Ratio > 90% 0.98 0.94 0.86 0.88 0.94 1.00 1.03
(13) FICO Score < 620 0.68 0.62 0.53 0.37 0.36 0.49 0.85
(14) ARMs 0.54 0.66 0.64 0.55 0.47 0.49 0.69
(15) High Risk Originations 0.82 0.79 0.74 0.64 0.59 0.63 0.88
(16) GSE Total Conforming Loans 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00
Sources: all data are from Federal Housing Administration (2010a).
25
Conforming mortgage originations exclude originations retained in lender portfolios.
26
Line (4) = (1) + (2) + (3) - adjustment for mortgages with multiple factors.
27
Relative intensity = GSE Share of Risk Attribute/GSE Share Conforming Loans (row 11).
62
Table 4
Conventional Single-Family Business Volume by Attribute and Year*
Fannie Mae
2001
2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007
LTV > 90% 11% 8% 7% 10% 9% 10% 16%
FICO < 620 6 6 4 6 5 6 6
ARMs 6 9 10 22% 21 17 10
Interest Only NA 1 1 5 10 15 16
Condo/Coop NA 7 7 9 10 11 11
Investor 4 5 6 4 5 6 5
Freddie Mac
LTV > 90% 11% 7% 5% 7% 6% 6% 11%
FICO < 620 4 3 3 4 4 5 6
ARMs 8 12 13 17 18 16 20
Interest Only NA NA NA 3 1 0 0
Condo/Coop NA NA NA NA NA NA NA
Investor 2 2 4 4 4 5 6
Source: Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac Annual Reports.
* Loans may have more than one of the characteristics.
63
Table 5
The Performance of European Mortgage Markets in Comparison with the US
*
Statistical Measures Computed with annual data by country for the years 1998 to 2010
Rate of
Owner
Occupancy
Latest Year
Coefficient of
Covariation
of Housing
Starts
1
Standard
Deviation of
House Price
Inflation
Mortgage
Adjustable
Rate Average
Level
Mortgage
Interest Rate
Average
Spread
2
Mortgage To
GDP Ratio
2010
Western Europe
Austria
57.5% 7.2% 2.7% 4.83% 1.79% 28.0%
Belgium
78.0% 15.2% 7.4% 5.61% 2.58% 46.3%
Denmark
53.6% 56.1% 8.5% 5.80% 2.58% 101.4%
Finland
59.0% 11.9% 3.8% 4.13% 1.09% 42.3%
France
57.8% 17.4% 6.2% 4.83% 1.80% 41.2%
Germany
43.2% 29.0% 1.7% 5.07% 2.05% 46.5%
Ireland
74.5% 99.2% 14.2% 4.32% 1.15% 87.1%
Italy
80.0% 25.7% 3.4% 4.70% 1.56% 22.7%
Luxembourg
70.4% 17.9% 4.7% 4.08% 1.05% 44.7%
Netherlands
55.5% 14.5% 6.5% 5.08% 2.06% 107.1%
Norway
85.0% 24.6% 5.0% 6.11% 1.44% 70.3%
Portugal
74.6% 35.5% 2.9% 4.43% 1.35% 66.3%
Spain
85.0% 93.0% 8.1% 4.16% 1.08% 64.0%
Sweden
66.0% 45.5% 2.9% 3.75% 0.91% 81.8%
United Kingdom
66.4% 25.0% 6.8% 5.12% 0.93% 85.0%
EU Average
67.1% 34.5% 5.6% 4.80% 1.56% 62.3%
US
66.9% 45.5% 7.3% 5.07% 2.26% 76.5%
US Rank
8
t
h
of 16 3rd of 16 5
t
h
of 16 6
t
h
of 16 3
r
d
of 16 6
t
h
of 16
*
Unless noted otherwise, the data are all from European Mortgage Federation (2009), an annual fact book that contains comprehensive mortgage and housing
market data for the years 1998 to 2009 for 15 Western European countries and the United States. 1) Computations based on housing starts where available; all
other countries use housing permits. 2) The mortgage interest rate spread is based on the 3-month Treasury Bill rate from the OECD Economic Outlook Date
Base.
Table 6
Effects of GSE Goals on Housing Market Outcomes
64
Author
Time
Period Data
Effect of Outcomes on
GSE Goals
Effect on Other
Housing Outcomes Remarks
Wyly and
Holloway
(2002)
1997-
2000
Loan applications from
HMDA
1% increase in subprime market
share leads to a rise in
nondisclosure (of race-
ethnicity) of 0.6% in the
refinance market. Nonreporting
rates are the highest in the
subprime refinance markets,
especially in inner city and low-
income areas.
An increasing number of
HMDA loan applications
contain no information on the
applicant’s race or ethnic
identity. They also conducted a
case study in Atlanta on the
disappearance of race data.
Ambrose
and
Thibodeau
(2004)
1995-
1999
Dollar volume of
purchase and refinance
loans from HMDA, by
MSA.
Lenders increased the
supply of mortgage
credit in areas with
higher proportions of
underserved borrowers.
Increases in GSE
purchases of seasoned
loans in an MSA lead
to increases in total
mortgage origination
volume in the MSA.
Volume of mortgages increased
steadily between 1995 and
1998, declining slightly in 1999.
27% increase in volume of
purchase mortgages by 1998,
and mortgage refinances
increased 211%. In 1999,
mortgage refinance volume fell
42% and purchase mortgage
volume increased another 12%.
1998 appears to be an unusual
year and significance of the
coefficients might arise from
the sudden increase in
mortgage purchase and
refinance volume that year.
Friedman
and Squires
(2005)
2000 Loan application and
purchase data from
2000 HMDA, by
MSA. Restricted to
conventional loans
originated to purchase
1-4 family homes.
Blacks and Latinos are more
likely to purchase homes in
predominantly white
neighborhoods in MSAs where
more loans are made by CRA
lenders.
Based on census tract racial
composition grouped into three
descriptive categories:
predominantly white, racially
integrated; and predominantly
minority.
Table 6
Effects of GSE Goals on Housing Market Outcomes (continued)
65
Author
Time
Period Data
Effect of Outcomes on
GSE Goals
Effect on Other
Housing Outcomes Remarks
Avery,
Bostic, and
Canner
(2005)
2000 Total lending and
lending experiences of
institutions from the
Survey of the
Performance and
Profitability of CRA-
Related Lending, 2000
Almost 60% of institutions
explicitly responded to CRA
obligations; half engaged in
community development
activities, and 30% had home
mortgage purchases and
refinance activities.
Survey conducted by the Board
of Governors of the Federal
Reserve to measure responses
of lending institutions to CRA.
Bostic and
Gabriel
(2006)
1994,
1999
GSE loan purchase
volume in California
census tracts analyzed
by MSA.
San Francisco MSA
had a greater increase
in homeownership
rates in designated
tracts. No significant
differences observed
elsewhere in
California.
No significant differences in
housing market performance
between GSE-targeted census
tracts and those just above and
below the GSE target.
Model relates breaks from 80-
90% and 90-100% of median
income census tract effects to
changes in housing market
outcomes
An and
Bostic
(2006)
1995-
2001
Shares of HMDA loans
sold on secondary
market, by purchasing
institution and census
tract.
1% increase in GSE
market share leads to
0.27% reduction in sub
market share.
Increases in GSE purchase
activity are associated with
declines in subprime mortgage
activity, especially in
neighborhoods with high
minority populations.
Effect of FHA growth on sub
market share is smaller.
An, Bostic,
Deng,
Gabriel,
Green, and
Tracy
(2007)
1995-
2000
Annual GSE home
loan-purchase, from
HMDA, by census
tract.
Increases in the percent
of GSE purchases by
tract are associated
with declines in
neighborhood vacancy
rates and increases in
median home values.
Significant deterioration in the
credit quality of FHA-insured
borrowers after 1996; GSEs
may have given FHA borrowers
in targeted tracts better access
to less expensive, conventional,
conforming loans
Possible endogenity: GSE
percent of purchase may be
function of other housing
market trends; GSE loan-
purchase may be a function of
housing market trends; GSEs
might simply shift their
purchase activity among
neighborhoods.
Table 6
Effects of GSE Goals on Housing Market Outcomes (continued)
66
Author
Time
Period Data
Effect of Outcomes on
GSE Goals
Effect on Other
Housing Outcomes Remarks
Laderman
and Reid
(2008)
2004-
2006
Loan application and
origination information
from HMDA, and loan
performance data from
Applied Analytics
(LPS). Analysis is
restricted to
conventional, first-lien,
owner-occupied loans
originated in MSAs in
California.
Loans made by a CRA lender
within its assessment area in
low-income neighborhoods
were less likely (odds ratio .73)
to be foreclosed than loans
made by IMCs in the same
neighborhoods. In moderate-
income neighborhoods, CRA
lenders were 1.7 times less
likely to be foreclosed.
Analyzed CRA mortgage
lending activities to measure
effect on current crisis, but did
not examine the impact that
CRA investment or service
components may have had on
the current financial crisis.
An and
Bostic
(2008)
1996 –
2002
HMDA loan level
application and
origination
information, matched
to census tracts.
Analysis is restricted to
owner-occupied home
purchase loans.
GSE market shares are
lower in central city
tracts and in tracts with
high minority
populations and high
vacancy rates. GSE
market shares are
higher in more affluent
census tracts (with
higher home values
and/or higher
incomes).
Negative and significant
correlation between GSE and
FHA market share, by census
tract.
FHA and GSE loan purchases
represent a small share of the
market of loans. Other factors
(like subprime mortgages)
could dominate the relationship
the authors found. The first
stage regression is problematic;
it showed no relationship
between targeted census tracts
and GSE market shares.
An and
Bostic
(2009)
1995-
2001
Shares of HMDA loans
sold on secondary
market, by purchasing
institution and census
tract.
Tracts with fewer total
loans have less GSE
penetration.
Negative relationship between
annual GSE purchase growth
and annual growth in subprime
loan originations. A 1
percentage point increase in
GSE share is associated with a
0.45 percentage point decline in
subprime market share.
GSEs do not purchase
subprime loans; this study is
based on TSLS regression.
Table 6
Effects of GSE Goals on Housing Market Outcomes (continued)
67
Author
Time
Period Data
Effect of Outcomes on
GSE Goals
Effect on Other
Housing Outcomes Remarks
Bhutta
(2009)
1997-
2004
Loan amounts,
originations, and loans
sold on secondary
market, by purchasing
institution and census
tract, from HMDA.
Analysis is restricted to
census tracts in MSAs.
Goals increased GSE
purchasing activity by
3-4% in targeted tracts
and increased GSE-
eligible originations by
2-3% on average.
No evidence that UAG-induced
increases in GSE credit supply
crowded out FHA and subprime
lending.
Regression discontinuity
design. In contrast to the An
and Bostic 2008 paper, Bhutta
estimates the impact of the
GSE Act separately on the
number of GSE purchases, the
total number of GSE-eligible
originations, and the number of
GSE-ineligible loans in
targeted tracts.
Bhutta
(2010a)
1994-
2002,
1998-
2005
Loan information by
lender type, application
status, loan purpose,
secondary purchaser (if
any) from HMDA, by
census tract of the
property and borrower
income.
On lending, CRA had
little impact, even
during the 2000s when
lending to lower
income areas soared.
Small increase in
nonbank lending in
CRA-targeted
neighborhoods of large
MSAs, particularly in
areas with historically
low home sales.
Increased bank lending does not
crowd out lending by mortgage
bank subsidiaries and
independent mortgage
companies.
Regression discontinuity
design. Limitation of RD
design is that it only measures
the CRA’s impact at the cutoff
(80 percent of median income),
so if there were a larger impact
for borrowers and
neighborhoods further below
the cutoff, the RD would
understate the CRA’s true
impact.
Table 6
Effects of GSE Goals on Housing Market Outcomes (continued)
68
Author
Time
Period Data
Effect of Outcomes on
GSE Goals
Effect on Other
Housing Outcomes Remarks
Bhutta
(2010b)
1997-
2002
Mortgage originations
and applications from
HMDA, by census
tracts in MSAs.
Small UAG effect on
GSE purchases and
mortgage originations.
GSEs purchase about
3.4% fewer loans in
tracts below the
eligibility cutoff.
No crowd out of FHA and
subprime lending.
Regression discontinuity
design. Analysis might
understate UAG’s effect
because RD can only identify
the goal’s impact for tracts near
the eligibility thresholds.
Bhutta notes that the UAG
mostly affects relatively stable
tracts, indicating that GSEs
respond where it is least costly.
Gabriel and
Rosenthal
(2010)
1994-
2008
Loan purchases and
originations from
HMDA, by census
tracts located within
MSAs. Census tracts
were adjusted to match
the 2000 census.
The disappearance of
GSE crowd out, with
the 2007 financial
crisis, suggests loans
purchased by GSEs
added substantively to
the flow of mortgage
credit.
From 1994-2003, GSE crowd
out of private secondary market
purchases was small. From
2004-2006, private loan
purchases expanded and GSE
crowd out estimates jumped to
50%. After 2007, GSE crowd
out was small again.
Addressed GSE purchase
endogeneity of instrumenting
for applications using lagged
tract homeownership rates.
Increased local secondary
market activity may result in
some easing in local
underwriting standards,
causing local applications to
increase. Thus OLS estimates
would be biased upwards. With
or without IVs, the trends were
similar.
Table 6
Effects of GSE Goals on Housing Market Outcomes (continued)
69
Author
Time
Period Data
Effect of Outcomes on
GSE Goals
Effect on Other
Housing Outcomes Remarks
Avery and
Brevoort
(20110)
2001,
2004-
2006
Loan origination and
purchases from
HMDA, by census
tract, with 3 outcome
variables: 1)
Percentage of
mortgage borrowers
who were 90 or more
days past due on at
least 1 mortgage
obligation, from
Equifax. 2) Percentage
of first-lien mortgage
loans originated in a
tract during 2004-2006
with estimated front-
end debt-to-income
ratios exceeding 30
percent, as a proxy for
high-risk or subprime
lending activity from
HMDA. 3) House price
changes between 2001-
2006 and 2006-2008
calculated from
HMDA.
No statistically
significant relationship
between loan sales to
the GSEs and
delinquency.
Found no evidence that CRA
and GSE goals contributed to
house price increases during the
2001-2006 buildup. CRA
targeted census tracts show
fewer loan delinquencies in
2008.
Regression discontinuity
design. Believes loan quality
and performance is important
to measure for GSE and CRA
goal success, in addition to
loan volume. Loan
performance data are missing;
they measured loan quality by
post-buildup delinquency rates
and risk characteristics. Also,
aggregation of analysis obscure
the fact that subprime boom
took on different forms in
different geographic regions.
Table 6
Effects of GSE Goals on Housing Market Outcomes (continued)
70
Author
Time
Period Data
Effect of Outcomes on
GSE Goals
Effect on Other
Housing Outcomes Remarks
Moulton
(2010)
1996-
1997,
2006-
2007
Loan originations and
purchases,
foreclosures,
vacancies, high-priced
loans, and other
housing outcomes from
HUD and HMDA by
census tract and also
by loan applicant.
Special Affordable
Goal increased GSE
purchases from very
low-income borrowers
by four percent but had
no effect on mortgage
lending.
No evidence that
LMIG or UAG altered
GSE purchase or
mortgage lending
decisions.
No relationship between GSE
Act’s affordable housing goals
and increased foreclosures,
vacancies, or other housing
outcomes.
Regression discontinuity
design. Diverges from Bhutta
2009 paper in a few ways.
Bhutta uses data aggregated to
the census tract-level, while
Moulton uses variation in loan
applicant-level data to examine
individual loan outcomes,
allowing Moulton to examine
the individual-level goals
outlined in the LMIG and
SAG.
71
Table 7
Estimates of GSE Funding Advantage
Author Data Comparison
Spread
in Basis
Points
US Treasury (1996) Bloomberg Agency vs
A Financials 53-55
Ambrose and Varga Fixed Income Fannie Mae vs
(1996) Research Program AA Financials 37-46
AA Corporate 38-39
A Financials 56-72
A Corporate 55-65
Freddie Mac Lehman Freddie vs
(1996) Relative Value AA & A 39
AAA 23
Toevs Lehman Fannie Mae vs
(2000) Bond Indexes AA-Indexes 37
Pearce and Miller Bloomberg Agency vs
(2001) AA Financials 37
Ambrose and Varga Fixed Investment Freddie and Fannie vs
(2002) Securities Database AA Banks 25-29
Nothaft, et al Fixed Investment Freddie and Fannie vs
(2002) Securities Database AA Debentures 30
A Debentures 45
AA MTNs 27
A MTNs 34
Passmore, et al Bloomberg Lehman Freddie and Fannie vs
(2005) AAA & AA Financials:
68 Firms 41
44 Firms 38
15 Firms 38
Source: Nothaft, et al (2002), Ambrose and Varga (2002), Passmore, et al, (2005). See Quigley (2006) for
additional details.
72
Table 8
Estimates of Reduction in Mortgage
Interest Rates Attributable
to GSEs
Author Time Period Region
Reduction in
Basis Points
Hendershott and Shilling (1989) 1986 California 24-39
ICF (1990) 1987 California
7 States
26
23
Cotterman and Pearce (1996) 1989-1993 California
11 States
25-50
24-60
Pearce (2000) 1992-1999 California
11 States
27
24
Ambrose, Buttimer and Thibodeau
(2001)
1990-1999 Dallas 16-24
Naranjo and Toevs (2002) 1986-1998 US 8-43
Passmore, Sparks and Ingpen
(2002)
1992-1999 California 18-23
CBO (2001) 1995-2000 US 23
McKenzie (2002) 1986-2000
1996-2000
US
US
22
19
Ambrose, La Cour-Little and
Saunders (2004)
1995-1997 US 6
Woodward 1996-2001 (2004b) 1996-2001 US 35-52
Passmore, Sherlan and Burgess
(2005)
1997-2003 US 15-18
Blinder, Flannery and Lockhart
(2006)
1997-2003 US 23-29
Source: McKenzie (2002); Ambrose (2004), Blinder, et al, (2006); Passmore, et al, (2005); Woodward (2004b). See
Quigley (2006) for details.
73
Table 9
Home Mortgage Activity, 2009 and 2010
Home Mortgage Activity in $ Billions 2009 2010 Total
Fannie Mae Mortgage Acquisitions 700 608 1,308
Freddie Mac Mortgage Acquisitions 475 386 861
Total GSE Mortgage Acquisitions 1,175 994 2,169
Total Home Mortgage Originations 1,840 1,630 3,470
Share of Total Home Mortgage Originations
GSE Share of Total Originations 64% 61% 63%
FHA and VA Share of Total Originations 24% 23% 24%
GSE, FHA, and VA Share of Total Originations 88% 84% 87%
Total GSE Refinanced Acquisitions 80% 79% 80%
Total Home Mortgage Refinancings 69% 67% 68%
Sources: Federal Housing Finance Agency 2010 Annual Report to Congress, Inside Mortgage Finance (for total and
refinanced mortgage originations), and Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac 2010 Annual Reports (for GSE refinancings).
74
Figure 1
Share of Whole Mortgages Held Directly, by Holder Class
(Source: See Data Appendix)
75
Figure 2
Share of MBS Outstanding, by Holder Class
(Source: See Data Appendix)
76
Figure 3
Share of Whole Mortgages and MBS, by Holder Class
(Source: See Data Appendix)
77
Figure 4
Share of MBS Outstanding, by MBS Issuer
(Source: See Data Appendix)
78
Figure 5
GSE "Low-Moderate Income" Housing Goal, 1993-2008
(Percent of New Loans to Households With Incomes Below Area Median Income)
Source: U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, Office of Policy Development and Research. "Overview of the GSEs'
Housing Goal Performance, 1993-2001", "Overview of the GSEs' Housing Goal Performance, 2000-2007,”
79
Figure 6
GSE "Underserved Area" Housing Goal, 1993-2008
(Percent of New Loans Credited Towards Goal)
Source: U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, Office of Policy Development and Research. "Overview of the GSEs'
Housing Goal Performance, 1993-2001", "Overview of the GSEs' Housing Goal Performance, 2000-2007."
80
Figure 7
GSE "Special Affordable" Housing Goal, 1993-2008
(Percent of New Loans Credited Towards Goal)
Source: U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, Office of Policy Development and Research. "Overview of the GSEs'
Housing Goal Performance, 1993-2001", "Overview of the GSEs' Housing Goal Performance, 2000-2007."
81
Figure 8
GSE “Low-Moderate Income” Housing Goals and Market Shares, 1993-2008
Source: Weicher, John C. "The Affordable Housing Goals, Homeownership and Risk: Some Lessons from Past Efforts to Regulate the
GSEs", Conference on "The Past, Present, and Future of the Government-Sponsored Enterprises", Federal Bank of St. Louis.
82
Figure 9
GSE “Underserved Area” Housing Goals and Market Shares, 1993-2008
Source: Weicher, John C. "The Affordable Housing Goals, Homeownership and Risk: Some Lessons from Past Efforts to Regulate the
GSEs", Conference on "The Past, Present, and Future of the Government-Sponsored Enterprises", Federal Bank of St. Louis.
83
Figure 10
GSE “Special Affordable” Housing Goals and Market Shares, 1993-2008
Source: Weicher, John C. "The Affordable Housing Goals, Homeownership and Risk: Some Lessons from Past Efforts to Regulate the
GSEs", Conference on "The Past, Present, and Future of the Government-Sponsored Enterprises", Federal Bank of St. Louis.
84
Figure 11
GSE “Special Affordable Multifamily” Housing Goals and GSE Purchases, 1993-2008*
Source: U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, Office of Policy Development and Research. "Overview of the GSEs'
Housing Goal Performance, 1993-2001", "Overview of the GSEs' Housing Goal Performance, 2000-2007."
* New loans to households residing in census tracts with incomes below the area median, in billions of dollars.
85
Figure 12
GSE Purchases of Multifamily Mortgages, 1985-2009
(as a percent of all mortgages)
Source: Federal Housing Finance Agency, Report to Congress 2009, Historical Data Tables; pp 125, 142.
86
Figure 13
Commercial and Multifamily Mortgage Bankers’ Originations
2004-2009
Source: Mortgage Bankers Association, September 2009
Appendix Table A1
Homeownership and Social Outcomes
87
Author
Time
Period Data Housing Outcome Observed Comments
Rossi and
Weber
(1996)
1988-
1995
General Social Survey
and the National Survey
of Families and
Households,
supplemented by data
from the American
National Election
Studies, by individual
Homeowners have slightly higher self-esteem,
life satisfaction, and are more involved with
community groups.
The effects of homeownership are not
large and sometimes inconsistent. It is
difficult to determine endogeneity.
Oswald
(1996)
1960s -
1990
Statistical Abstract and
Eurostat, by country
Homeownership reduces workers’ mobility,
thus causing them to stay unemployed longer. A
ten percent increase in homeownership is
associated with approximately a two percent
increase in unemployment.
Small sample sizes makes the results
unreliable.
Green and
White
(1997)
1980-
1987
Panel Study of Income
Dynamics (PSID), the
Public Use Microsample
of the 1980 Census of
Population and Housing
(PUMS), and High
School and Beyond
(HSB), by child
Adjusting for income and parental differences in
the PSID data, children of owner-occupied
homes have a predicted probability of
completing high school of .91, compared to .82
for renters. The differential falls as income
rises. In the PUMS, homeowner children had a
.9 probability of being in school, compared to
.83 for children of renters at the same age.
The HSB data comes from parents who
completed high school. Probit models
are used to account for selection bias
due to differences between parents
who own and rent. Also, using the
lifetime earnings differential between a
high school dropout and a high school
graduate, the benefit of a government
policy to encourage low income renters
to own homes is estimated to be about
$31,000.
Appendix Table A1
Homeownership and Social Outcomes (continued)
88
Author
Time
Period Data Housing Outcome Observed Comments
DiPasquale
and Glaeser
(1999)
1972-
1994
General Social Survey,
German Socio-Economic
Panel, by individual
Controlling for age, race, sex, marital status,
children, income, education, residential
structure type, and city size, homeowners are
roughly 10% more likely to know their US
representative, 9% more likely to know the
identity of their school board head, 15% more
likely to vote in local elections, 6% more likely
to work to solve local problems, than renters.
Homeowners invest more in social capital and
local amenities. Homeowners are better citizens.
Authors use the average
homeownership rate of the individual’s
income quartile as an instrument for
homeownership. They could not
measure the extent of the positive
externalities. They also found
homeowners are less likely to move
than renters. The cost of immobility is
not calculated.
Aaronson
(2000)
1975-
1993
Panel Study of Income
Dynamics, children aged
7 to 16
For the base case, where the child is white,
male, lives in a household with married parents,
two siblings, average income, and the head of
household is a high school graduate, the
probability of graduating from high school for
children who live in owner occupied housing is
1.5% higher than renters. Latent family stability
factors explain as least 20% of the
homeownership effect.
Response to the Green and White
paper. Argues that a child’s school
graduation does not depend on
homeownership as much as it depends
on the stability homeownership offers
the child.
Green and
Hendershott
(2001)
1986-
1992
Panel Survey of Income
Dynamics, by individual
A ten-percentage point increase in
homeownership increases unemployment by
months. four percent increase
Response to Oswald paper. There are
seasonal effects of unemployment and
how quickly unemployed individuals
find work. For example, in 1988, heads
of households who became
unemployed were reemployed
significantly quicker in December than
in other months.
Appendix Table A1
Homeownership and Social Outcomes (continued)
89
Author
Time
Period Data Housing Outcome Observed Comments
Boyle
(2002)
1983 Ontario Child Health
Study, the National
Longitudinal Study of
Children and Youth, by
child
The correlation between home ownership and
child problem behavior was -0.18. The
correlation between neighborhood
homeownership rates and the incidence of child
problems was not significant.
The study controlled for
socioeconomic differences between
owners and renters, but not for other
parental characteristics like the
physical, mental, and social health of
the parents, which might have also
affected the association between home
ownership and child problem behavior.
Haurin,
Parcel, and
Haurin
(2002)
1988,
1990,
1992,
1994
National Longitudinal
Survey of Youth,
children aged five to
eight
The longer a parent owns a home, the greater
the child’s cognition skills and the fewer the
child’s behavior problems. The correlation
between homeownership with “Behavior
Problems Index” is -0.07.
The explanatory variables included
both contemporaneous home
ownership and duration of home
ownership. (Controlling also for the
mother’s and father’s characteristics
separately education, wage, and race,
as well as socioeconomic variables, for
community factors like neighborhood
characteristics.)
Conley and
Gifford
(2006)
1981-
1994
Luxembourg Income
Study, Comparative
Welfare States Data Set,
by country
Compared different countries and found that
more widespread home ownership is positively
associated with higher income inequality and
negatively associated with welfare spending. A
one percentage point increase in social
insurance spending by the government results in
0.75 percentage point decrease in
homeownership.
This study does not measure the causal
directionality of homeownership,
social insurance, and welfare.
Munch,
Rosholm,
and Svarer
(2007)
1993-
2001
Statistics Denmark
administrative registers,
by individual
Homeowners have a 29% lower unemployment
risk than renters. Homeowners have a wage
premium 5.37% higher than renters and owners
set higher reservation wages for jobs outside the
local labor market relative to renters.
Crude estimates.
Appendix Table A1
Homeownership and Social Outcomes (continued)
90
Author
Time
Period Data Housing Outcome Observed Comments
Coulson and
Li (2010)
1989,
1993
American Housing
Survey, by cluster
Income increases with higher ownership rates,
but the results are small and sometimes
insignificant. The transition of a home from
rental to ownership in a typical neighborhood
creates $1000-3000 per year in positive
externality value.
Measured the units of observation by
neighborhood cluster, which typically
had 11 houses.