THE EARLY MODERN GREAT DIVERGENCE: WAGES, PRICES AND
ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT IN EUROPE AND ASIA, 1500-1800
Stephen Broadberry and Bishnupriya Gupta
Department of Economics, University of Warwick, Coventry CV4 7AL, United
Kingdom
S.N.Broadberr[email protected]
29 September 2003
File: wage7a
Abstract: Contrary to the claims of Pomeranz, Parthasarathi and other “world
historians”, the prosperous parts of Asia between 1500 and 1800 look similar to the
stagnating southern, central and eastern parts of Europe rather than the developing
northwestern parts. In the advanced parts of India and China, grain wages were
comparable to those in northwestern Europe, but silver wages, which conferred
purchasing power over tradable goods and services, were substantially lower. The
high silver wages of northwestern Europe were not simply a monetary phenomenon,
but reflected high productivity in the tradable sector. The “Great Divergence”
between Europe and Asia was already well underway before 1800.
JEL classification: N10, N30, O10
Key words: Wages, prices, development, Europe, Asia
Acknowledgements: We would like to thank, without in any way implicating, Bob
Allen, Jörg Baten, V. Bhaskar, Kent Deng, Rainer Fremdling, Regina Grafe, George
Grantham, Tim Guinnane, Irfan Habib, Angus Maddison, Shireen Moosvi, Patrick
O’Brien, Kevin O’Rourke, Sevket Pamuk, Albrecht Ritschl, Peter Wardley, Nuala
Zahedieh and seminar/conference participants at Berlin, Copenhagen, Dublin,
Durham, Madrid, Nashville and Warwick for helpful comments and discussions.
2
I. INTRODUCTION
World historians such as Pomeranz (2000), Parthasarathi (1998; 2001) and Frank
(1998) have recently claimed that the Great Divergence between Europe and Asia
occurred only after 1800, and that before that date, the most advanced parts of Europe
and Asia should be seen as on the same development level, with multiples cores and
shared constraints (Pomeranz, 2000: 107). In this paper, however, we argue that the
most advanced parts of Asia in 1800 should be seen as on the same development level
as the stagnating parts of the European periphery. Although it is possible to show that
grain wages were still close to northwest European levels in the most advanced parts
of Asia in 1800, silver wages were a fraction of northwest European levels.
Furthermore, the geographical distribution of silver wages corresponds to the
established pattern shown by other indicators of economic development, such as the
urbanization ratio.
Pomeranz (2000) argues that per capita food consumption and the purchasing
power of wages measured in terms of calories was as high in the Yangzi delta region
of China as in the most developed parts of Europe as late as the end of the eighteenth
century. Similarly, Parthasarathi (1998, 2001) argues that during the eighteenth
century, wages in southern India could purchase about the same amount of Indian
grain as wages in Britain could purchase British grain. Parthasarathi (1998: 101-102),
however, also emphasizes the low purchasing power of Indian wages measured in
grams of silver. He treats this as evidence of the low price of grain in southern India,
which he sees as the result of high agricultural productivity. However, we need to be
careful here before we follow Pomeranz (2000) and Parthasarathi (1998) in regarding
the Yangzi delta region of China, southern India and other parts of Asia as on the
3
same development level as the most developed parts of Europe such as Britain and the
Netherlands. For this pattern of high wages measured in terms of the amount of grain
they could purchase, but low wages in terms of the silver content of the currency in
which they were paid, was also a feature of the less developed parts of southern,
central and eastern Europe during the early modern period. We argue, therefore, that
by the eighteenth century the more economically advanced parts of Asia should be
seen as on the same level as the more peripheral rather than the most developed parts
of Europe.
We argue that the high silver wages of northwestern Europe were not simply a
monetary phenomenon resulting from an inflow of New World bullion, but reflected
high productivity in the traded goods sector. Although the bullion flowed in through
Spain, prices rose by a similar amount in most European countries. Despite this, silver
wage leadership passed from the south to the north, with England showing the most
rapid growth. The gap between the silver wage and the grain wage can hence be
used as an indicator of the level of development. This conforms with the well known
tendency for both wages and prices to be higher in developed economies, so that
international comparison of wages at the official exchange rate gives a misleading
impression of the gap in living standards btween developed and underdeveloped
countries (Balassa, 1964; Samuelson, 1964). However, it also confirms, in the context
of the Europe-Asia nexus, the early existence of some of the key features of the
relationship between a developed and a less developed country (LDC): (1) Wages in
the LDC meet the food needs of the population given the price of food in the LDC,
but would not purchase sufficient food in the developed country at developed country
prices (2) Manufactures produced in the LDC are relatively expensive within the LDC
4
(at local relative prices), but are competitive on world markets because of the low
wages measured in developed country prices.
The paper proceeds as follows. Section II establishes the pattern of an
emerging silver wage leadership in northwestern Europe despite the absence of any
clear grain wage leadership before the nineteenth century, and shows how this pattern
is related to other indicators of development such as urbanization. Sections III and IV
then shows how regions of India and China, respectively, look more like the
stagnating parts of southern, eastern and central Europe than the modernizing parts of
northwestern Europe. Despite the high grain wages emphasized by world historians,
the most advanced parts of Asia also had very low silver wages and low levels of
urbanization. Section V demonstrates that the high silver wages of northwestern
Europe cannot be dismissed as a purely monetary phenomenon, but reflected high
productivity in the traded goods sector.
II. WAGES AND PRICES IN EUROPE
1. Silver wages and grain wages
Largely as a result of the pioneering work of the International Committee on Price
History during the 1930s, it is possible to gather data on the daily wages of unskilled
and skilled building workers in many European cities and regions between 1500 and
1800, and to compare them in terms of both the silver content of the local currencies
and the volume of grain that they could purchase (Beveridge, 1939: xlix-li).
Following van Zanden (1999), the former is called the silver wage and the latter the
grain wage. The pattern of silver wages in Europe is shown in Table 1, taken from
Allen (2001: 416), where the data are presented as averages over periods of fifty years
5
to deal with problems of volatility and information gaps for particular years (van
Zanden, 1999: 179).
The key findings are as follows: (1) Northwestern Europe saw substantial
silver wage growth, with Britain overtaking the Netherlands during the eighteenth
century. (2) In southern Europe there were considerable fluctuations but less trend
growth in the silver wage, starting from about the same level as northwestern Europe
in 1500. (3) In central and eastern Europe, as in southern Europe, there were
substantial fluctuations in silver wages but only weak trend growth, starting from a
significantly lower level than northwestern Europe in 1500. (4) The regional variation
is broadly similar for skilled and unskilled workers, with a skill premium of around 50
per cent in northwestern Europe, but rising closer to 100 per cent in much of southern,
central and eastern Europe.
The pattern of silver wages is therefore broadly in line with conventional
views about the level of development in different parts of Europe, with northwestern
Europe pulling ahead of the previously more developed south, and with central and
eastern Europe continuing to lag behind. Indeed, van Zanden (1999: 181) notes a
strong positive correlation between the silver wage by country and the urbanization
ratio by country.
Grain wages for the same cities and regions, where available, are presented in
Table 2. Here, wages are compared in terms of the volume of wheat or rye that they
could buy, given the local prices of grain. This was usually wheat in northwestern and
southern Europe and rye in central and eastern Europe (apart from Vienna). In
6
Holland, where both grains were widely available, rye sold for about two-thirds the
price of wheat (van Zanden, 1999: 184). The grain wages in Table 2 show almost the
mirror image of the silver wages in Table 1, with a negative trend in all regions, and
with the highest level of grain wages in central and eastern Europe. This suggests that
the high silver wages of the developing parts of Europe were not actually enabling
people to buy more food.
2. Relative prices and real consumption wages
High and rising silver wages in northwestern Europe did not translate into high grain
wages before the nineteenth century. However, real consumption wages may still
have risen through increased consumption of non-agricultural goods and services, the
prices of which were falling relative to the price of grain. In England, for example, we
know that the price of farinaceous goods (including wheat, barley, rye, peas and
potatoes) increased by a factor of nine between the mid-fifteenth century and the end
of the eighteenth century, while the price of textiles increased only by a factor of three
(Phelps Brown and Hopkins, 1981: 44-59).
Phelps Brown and Hopkins (1981) calculate price indices for each country
based on non-food items as well as food, so that it is possible to examine trends in real
consumption wages within individual countries, but not to compare real consumption
wages between countries. Following Allen (2001), however, it is possible to compare
European real consumption wages across both space and time. The results in Table 3
compute the real consumption wage of unskilled building laborers in European
countries over the period 1500-49 to 1800-49, using the data on silver wages from
Table 1 together with Allens (2001: 426) data on the price of a basket of
7
commodities in each city in each period. The results have been reported here with
London 1500-49 as the base.
1
The real consumption wage data in Table 3 remove the most perplexing aspect
of the real grain wage data in Table 2, the apparently higher living standards in central
and eastern Europe. The real consumption wage data show the opening of a gap
between northwestern Europe on the one hand and southern, central and eastern
Europe on the other hand, as in the silver wage data of Table 1. This means that the
high grain wages of central and eastern Europe, noted by van Zanden (1999) and
shown here in Table 2, did not translate into high real consumption wages. As Allen
(2001: 419-420) notes, urban wage earners purchased bread rather than grain and
there were other non-grain items in the consumption basket.
However, Allens real consumption wage data do not remove altogether the
pessimistic view of declining living standards in Europe between 1500 and 1800,
previously suggested by Abel (1980), Braudel and Spooner (1967) and van Zanden
(1999). They suggest, rather, that the divergence between living standards in the
developed parts of northwestern Europe and the less developed parts of southern,
central and eastern Europe occurred as a result of constant real wages in the northwest
and collapsing real wages in the other regions. This finding is, however, based on the
assumption of a constant number of days worked per year, so that daily wage rates
can be taken as representative of annual earnings. This assumption can be criticized
1
Allen (2001: 428) reports his results in the form of welfare ratios. Assuming a working year of 250
days, on the basis of a 5-day working week for 50 weeks, Allen (2001: 424-431) computes an annual
income for a building laborer and compares it to a notional poverty line for a family consisting of a
man, a woman and two children consuming a few basic products. The poverty line is calculated taking
account of some important differences in national climate and cuisine, and allowing for local prices.
8
on the grounds that it neglects to take account of the Industrious Revolution (de
Vries, 1994).
The Industrious Revolution was proposed by de Vries (1993: 107) as a
solution to the conundrum that despite the apparent constancy of real daily wage rates
in Europe during the early modern period, the evidence from probate inventories and
direct consumption measures reveals an ever-multiplying world of goods, a richly
varied and expanding material culture, with origins going back to the seventeenth
century and exhibiting a social range extending far down the hierarchy. For de Vries
(1994: 257), the Industrious Revolution consisted of a new strategy of household
utility maximization, involving a reduction of leisure time and a reallocation of labor
from non-market to market activities, so as to allow increased consumption of market-
supplied goods. He sees the process as containing a demand-side element through
changing tastes, and not simply as a response to commercial incentives such as
changing relative prices and reduced transactions costs (de Vries, 1994: 256).
Allowing for the Industrious Revolution would produce a modest trend rise of
the real wage in northwestern Europe. For example, in London we might allow for an
increase in the number of days worked per year from 250 to 300 between 1750-99 and
1850-49 in line with Voths (1998) evidence on the decline of St. Monday. We
might also allow for an increase in the number of days worked per year from 200 to
250 between 1500-49 and 1550-99, in line with the evidence of de Vries (1993: 110-
111) on the large reduction in the number of feast days following the Reformation.
This would produce an increase in the real consumption wages of unskilled laborers
The resulting welfare ratio of earnings relative to the poverty line, can be thought of as a peculiarly
9
in London of 0.13 per cent per annum over the 300 years following 1500-49, and still
by only 0.19 per cent per annum over the 200 years following 1600-49.
3. Structural change and urbanization
Another way in which the daily wage data could be seen as consistent with an upward
trend in real living standards would be if there was substantial structural change, with
a shift from low paid agricultural jobs in rural areas to higher paying industrial
employment in urban areas. Since Crafts and Harley (1992) estimate that per capita
income in Britain grew at an annual rate of 0.32 per cent per annum between 1700
and 1830, rising to 0.5 per cent per annum between 1800 and 1830, there would be
plenty of room for effects arising from an Industrious Revolution and structural
change.
To see the extent of structural change with economic development, we can
chart the patterns of urban population shares in Table 4, derived from de Vries (1984).
The urban share of the population is based here on cities of more than 10,000
inhabitants.
2
During the Middle Ages, the most developed parts of Europe were in the
Mediterranean region, centered particularly on Spain and northern Italy, and there was
a further center of development based on Belgium and the Netherlands in
northwestern Europe. Urban development lagged behind in central and eastern
Europe. During the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, urban and non-agricultural
activity stagnated in Spain and Italy, so that the center of gravity moved to
scaled real wage index (Allen, 2001: 427).
2
Bairoch (1976) provides alternative urbanization ratios for cities of more than 5,000 inhabitants, but
inhabitants of smaller cities are added to the large cities in constant proportion, a procedure criticized
strongly by de Vries (1984: 347). Bairochs figures are used by Allen (2000: 8-9), and suggest some
different trends in individual countries, but not for Europe as a whole. The agreement between de Vries
10
northwestern Europe, with England emerging as the most dynamic region of urban
and non-agricultural development. Urban development continued to lag behind in
central and eastern Europe.
Recent work on economic geography and development has placed
considerable emphasis on external economies of scale associated with urbanization as
well as localization. Economies of localization refer to the benefits derived by a
producer from the proximity of other producers in the same industry, and can be
linked to the work of Marshall [1920], who stressed the flows of specialized
information, the availability of a skilled labor supply and specialized machine
builders, and thick markets for other inputs and outputs. However, the formation of
industrial districts to reap economies of localization does not necessarily imply
large-scale urbanization, and may be quite consistent with proto-industrialization
(Mendels, 1972). Jacobs (1969), however, emphasizes the benefits derived by a
producer from the wider infrastructure associated with the spatial concentration of a
diverse range of industries. Such benefits cannot, by definition, be realized in a proto-
industrial setting. The recent literature of writers such as Glaeser et al. (1992) and
Henderson et al. (1995) is thus consistent with the skeptical view of proto-
industrialisation as a stage on the road to modern economic growth expressed by
writers such as Coleman (1983) and Clarkson (1985). Rural peasants supplementing
their agricultural incomes with some industrial production should not be confused
with specialized industrial production in highly urbanized economies. Note, further,
that high productivity in the traded goods sector in northwestern Europe may be seen
as arising through merchant distribution and finance as much as through production.
and Bairoch at the level of Europe as a whole appears to be due to an error in Bairochs total
11
The service sector can thus be seen as playing a crucial role in economic growth
during the early modern period, as in the modern period (Broadberry, 1998;
Broadberry and Ghosal, 2002; 2003).
4. Distribution and relative prices
If living standards of northwest Europeans increased through the falling relative price
of manufactured goods rather than through increased consumption of basic foodstuffs
such as grain, it is likely that the fruits of early modern development were spread
unevenly. Clearly, the wages of skilled laborers in Tables 1 and 2 yielded a larger
surplus over basic food needs than the wages of unskilled laborers. And if wages only
covered basic needs, there was little scope to benefit from the falling relative price of
manufactures. Hoffman et al. (2002: 334) show that during the early modern period,
the relative price of luxuries was declining, so that the gains were greatest of all for
the top 20 per cent of the income distribution.
To summarize the situation in Europe, we see the following patterns: (1)
During the Middle Ages, the highest silver wages were recorded in southern Europe,
but during the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries silver wage leadership passed to
northwestern Europe. (2) These developments were closely linked to urban and non-
agricultural development, with stagnation in southern Europe and dynamic growth in
northwestern Europe, particularly England. (3) These silver wage patterns are not
reflected in the grain wage; people moving to the towns with economic development
were not able to buy more food, and any gain in overall living standards for laborers
in northwestern Europe was modest before the early nineteenth century.
population estimates which offsets the error in the urban population estimates.
12
To understand the Great Divergence between Europe and Asia, we need to
know if the more advanced parts of Asia looked more like northwestern Europe (high
silver wages but modest grain wages for the mass of laborers) or more like southern,
central and eastern Europe (low silver wages as well as modest grain wages). We now
turn to an examination of wages and prices in India and China.
III. WAGES AND PRICES IN INDIA
1. Silver wages and grain wages
Data on money wages and grain prices expressed in silver content are readily
available for India from a number of sources. The starting point is Mughal India under
Akbar, for which we have surprisingly detailed information on wages and prices from
$E ¶OFazls [1595] remarkable document, 7KH ¶ Q±L$NEDU . This provides
information on the day wages of unskilled and skilled workers in northern India in
1595. For the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries the main source are the records of
the English and Dutch East India Companies. For the nineteenth century the data
come from statistical records produced by government. Although a number of studies
have attempted to compare the purchasing power of the wages of unskilled laborers
between 1595 and the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, there has been less
work on the intervening period (Desai, 1972; 1978; Moosvi, 1973; 1977; Heston,
1977). Furthermore, these studies do not place Indian experience in an international
context. We now turn to establishing the level of silver wages and grain wages in
India at a number of points between 1595 and 1874 in units that will facilitate a
comparison with Europe. We also address the issue of regional variations within
13
India, following the claim of Parthasarasthi (1998; 2001) that grain wages in southern
India were on a par with British grain wages during the eighteenth century.
Table 5 presents data on daily wages of unskilled and skilled laborers in terms
of both their silver content and the amount of grain that they could purchase. Part A
provides data for northern and western India, based on the cities of Agra and Surat.
Wages in rupees are converted to grams of silver using information from Habib
(1978) and Chaudhuri (1978). The broad trend is for the silver wage to rise, with the
skilled wage about double the unskilled wage, as in the peripheral rather than core
northwestern parts of Europe. The rising silver wage is consistent with the constancy
of the money wage expressed in copper dams per day, since the price of silver
depreciated relative to copper (Habib, 1978: 370). Our findings are thus broadly
consistent with those of Mukerjee (1967: 26).
We then use the price of grain to convert the money wages into grain wages.
The data are presented in terms of both wheat and rice, and for both unskilled and
skilled workers. In contrast to the rising trend in silver wages, grain wages trended
downwards in northern and western India, as money wages failed to keep up with the
rising trend in grain prices, particularly during the early seventeenth century. Brennig
(1986: 349) argues that subsistence consumption for a household of six was 3.1 kg of
rice per day. Taking the wheat/rice ratio of calories per lb from Parthasarathi (1998:
83) yields a subsistence consumption of 4.7 kg of wheat per day for a family of six.
On this basis, grain wages were always above subsistence for skilled workers, but fell
below the subsistence level for unskilled workers during the early seventeenth
century.
14
In southern India, money wage rates are usually available in units of the
pagoda, a gold coin. These pagoda rates are converted to silver rupees using East
India Company standard rates from Chaudhuri (1978: 471). Although the bulk of the
figures for southern India appear to fit quite well with the figures for northern and
western India, the figures for 1750 stand out as substantially higher. These figures are
taken from Parthasarathi (1998) and are placed in parentheses because we think they
are unrepresentative and therefore misleading as a guide to overall wage levels in
southern India.
Parthasarathi (1998: 84, 97) argues that a relatively unskilled weaver could
earn 5 pagodas in two months, which would allow a weekly purchase of 65 lb of rice.
This is consistent with the standard data on the price of rice in southern India in the
mid-eighteenth century from Arasaratnam (1980: 270) at 105 lb per pagoda (or 33 lb
per rupee). However, the wage rate is roughly twice the average from other sources,
including unskilled wage rates from Arasaratnam (1980: 343) for the same occupation
in the same area at around the same time. Parthasarathi (1998: 84, fn20) claims that
his high grain wage estimates are supported by the figures of Brennig (1986).
However, Brennig (1986: 349) actually works with quite low monthly earnings of
unskilled weavers (1 pagoda), and obtains his estimates of a high grain wage by using
an exceptionally low rice price (400 lb per pagoda). Neither Parthasarathis high
money wage nor Brennigs low grain price fits into the wider picture of trends over
time and across regions.
2. Regional issues
15
Parthasarathi (1998: 102) suggests that the high grain wages which he claims for
southern India were the result of the high productivity of rice-growing agriculture.
This is of particular interest because the part of China that Pomeranz (2000) claims
had living standards on a par with Britain in the eighteenth century, the Yangzi delta,
is also a rice-growing area. Furthermore, Mukerjees (1967: 44, 49) figures for Bengal
in the eighteenth century are also consistent with high grain wages despite low silver
wages, due to the cheap price of rice. One way of explaining the high standard of
living being claimed for parts of Asia in the eighteenth century, then, may simply be
to see it as a result of the naturally high yield of grain in rice-growing areas. The
reduced need for shelter, fuel and clothing in a warm climate may be seen as further
reinforcing this effect. But this is clearly not the message that world historians
would wish to draw, and Parthasarathi (2001: 43-53) claims that the high productivity
of southern Indian agriculture was the result not of geographical factors, but of high
levels of investment during the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries.
Parthasarathis explanation of how the investment in southern Indian
agriculture came about and how it led to both high levels of economic development
and low silver wages raises a number of serious logical difficulties. In the developing
parts of northwestern Europe, institutional change is usually seen as bringing about
investment in agriculture, leading in turn to high agricultural labor productivity.
However, this higher agricultural labor productivity did not lead to an abundance of
grain and low food prices, because labor moved out of agriculture into industry and
services. Rising living standards came from increasing consumption of cheaper
industrial goods, together with relatively constant consumption of food. In
Parthasarthis (2001: 43-53) view of southern India, however, investment in
16
agriculture was the result of rulers competing to attract and fix mobile labor. This
investment is then seen as leading to an abundance of grain, and low food prices.
Given the low price of food, it was then possible to pay low money wages to laborers
in industry, and Indian industrial goods were highly competitive on world markets.
However, this raises more questions than it answers: (1) Why did competition
between Indian rulers for laborers take the form of investment in land improvements
rather than direct payments to laborers? (2) Why did rising productivity in Indian
agriculture lead to an abundance of grain rather than a reallocation of labor to industry
and services? (3) Why did the relative abundance of grain lead to a low overall price
level rather than just a low relative price of grain (or high relative price of other
goods)? (4) Suppose the absolute price level did start out low, making Indian textiles
cheap on world markets. That should have caused an inflow of bullion, which should
have raised the Indian price level. How could such equilibrating forces have been
offset for two centuries?
A more plausible view is that southern India did have an abundance of rice
arising from natural geographical factors, together with a high proportion of the labor
force engaged in agriculture. However, the cloth export industry was but a small part
of a larger economy that produced at low levels of average labor productivity. This
more traditional view of southern India would also be consistent with the evidence on
urbanization, which sees the north as more urban than the south (Hambly and Stein,
1978; Blake, 1987).
3
In this view, southern India would be more akin to Poland than
3
The urban population in India during Akbars reign has been estimated at 15 per cent, made up of 120
big cities and 3,200 townships, although the latter includes settlements of less than 10,000 inhabitants.
The urbanization ratio declined in the nineteenth century, and the sixteenth century ratio was not
attained again until the second half of the twentieth century (Habib, 1999: 84-85).
17
Britain in the eighteenth century, with high grain wages reflecting an abundance of
grain and low silver wages reflecting low levels of overall development.
3. An Anglo-Indian comparison
Table 6 allows a direct Anglo-Indian comparison of silver wages and grain wages for
unskilled workers. The Indian silver wage for unskilled laborers was little more than a
fifth of its English counterpart at the end of the sixteenth century, and it fell to little
more than one-seventh of the English level during the eighteenth century. We have
excluded Parthasarathis (1998) estimates from this table since we think they
exaggerate the Indian level of wages in the mid-eighteenth century. But even if these
estimates were included, they would merely show Indian silver wages temporarily
shooting up to about 40 per cent of the British level in the first half of the eighteenth
century. The silver wage data suggest unambiguously, then, that the Great Divergence
was already well established in the sixteenth century.
Although the Indian grain wage remained close to the English level until the
end of the seventeenth century, our data indicate a sharp divergence during the
eighteenth century. This divergence occurred partly as a result of a rise in the English
grain wage, but also partly as a result of a decline in the Indian grain wage. This
means that India looks rather more like the peripheral parts of southern, central and
eastern Europe than the developing parts of northwestern Europe. In short, India was
not on the same development level as Britain during the seventeenth and eighteenth
centuries.
18
IV. WAGES AND PRICES IN CHINA
1. Silver wages and grain wages
Detailed data on grain prices are readily available for Qing dynasty China (1644-
1911), as a result of a system of price reports recording the highest and lowest prices
in each prefecture during each lunar month (Wang, 1972; 1992; Chuan and Kraus,
1975: 1-16). However, there is no equivalent of the systematic money wage data
available in Europe, due to the fact that money wages were typically supplemented by
substantial food allowances (Pomeranz, 2000: 319-320). Even in late nineteenth
century Beijing, Gamble (1943: 66) finds food money exceeding money wages for
unskilled men working with the carpenters and masons guilds. Scattered estimates
of the total wage (including food) paid to hired laborers in Chinese agriculture are
available, however, and we shall make use of these. We shall focus on the Yangzi
delta region, since it has been claimed by Pomeranz (2000) that this was not only the
most advanced part of China throughout the period under consideration, but was also
as economically developed as the most advanced parts of northwestern Europe.
These data in Table 7 show a small drop in Yangzi delta money wages
between the Late Ming and Mid Qing periods. Converting the money wage in taels
into grams of silver enables us to make a comparison with the silver wage in Europe
and India. The unskilled silver wage in China was about the same as the unskilled
silver wage in India, and a small fraction of the silver wage in northwestern Europe.
With the price of rice increasing between the Late Ming and Mid Qing periods, grain
wages declined sharply. Grain wages in the Yangzi delta were of the same order of
magnitude as in India.
19
The declining grain wage is easier to reconcile with the picture of Yangzi delta
agriculture in the work of Huang (1990; 2002) and Brenner and Isett (2002) than with
the more optimistic picture in Pomeranz (2000) and Li (1998). Huang (1990) uses the
term involution to describe Yangzi delta agriculture, and Chinese agriculture more
generally. As the size of peasant farms declined with population growth, average farm
size became too small to support a peasant household through agricultural production,
and household incomes were maintained by participation in low productivity textile
production. By contrast, Li (1998) argues for rising agricultural labor productivity in
the Yangzi delta between the Late Ming and Mid Qing periods. Although at first sight
Li (1998) appears to provide quantitative evidence to support his view, it must be
emphasized that he has merely constructed stylized examples based on Chinese
agricultural handbooks of the time. Furthermore, these examples are based on the
assumption that the original yield data in the agricultural handbooks are always
reported in terms of husked rice rather than unhusked paddy. This makes quite a
difference, because 1 shi of paddy yields just 0.5 shi of husked rice (Li, 1998: xvii). If
the original yield data refer sometimes to unhusked paddy, as suggested by Perkins
(1969: 318-319), labor productivity levels and trends could be substantially altered.
The Chinese wage data show the same basic patterns as the Indian wage data.
The Anglo-Chinese comparison in Table 8 thus shows a very similar picture to the
Anglo-Indian comparison on Table 6. The silver wage was already much lower in
China than in Britain by the Late Ming period, while the Chinese grain wage had also
fallen decisively behind by the Mid Qing period.
2. Urbanization and the structure of the economy
20
It is possible to derive estimates of the extent of urbanization in China on a
comparable basis to the estimates of de Vries (1984) for Europe (Maddison, 1998: 33-
36). Although Rozman (1973) focuses on urbanization ratios for all levels of central
places, he presents enough information to derive estimates for cities of at least 10,000
inhabitants (levels 1-4). Table 9 presents estimates on both bases, together with the
data on cities of at least 10,000 inhabitants for Europe. On a comparable basis, it is
clear that urbanization was already higher in Europe than in China during the Ming
dynasty, and that Europes advantage had grown substantially by the early nineteenth
century (particularly in England and Wales). Furthermore, the regional breakdown of
urbanization ratios for China in Table 10 does not suggest a development gradient
anything like as steep as in Europe. The most developed part of China, the Yangzi
delta, is in Jiangsu in east central China. Although the urbanization ratio was highest
in this region, the scale of the difference with the poorer regions was not particularly
large. Li (1998: 21-23) argues that Rozmans Jiangsu figure for all urban settlements
is an under-estimate for the Yangzi delta, but his suggestion of an urbanization ratio
for the latter of 15 per cent in 1700 is still way below the level in the Netherlands
(33.6 per cent, even when the Netherlands figure is restricted to cities of more than
10,000). In short, there is nothing in the urbanization ratios to suggest that China or
the Yangzi delta were on the same development level as northwestern Europe.
V. SILVER AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT
1. Bullion flows and price inflation
Grain wages in India and China appear to have been quite close to levels in
northwestern Europe until the end of the seventeenth century. Given the potential for
measurement errors, it would be difficult to argue on the basis of this evidence alone
21
that the Great Divergence between Europe and Asia was already strongly underway
before the eighteenth century. Rather, it is the combination of this modest grain wage
gap together with the evidence of a much larger silver wage gap that we think adds up
to a strong case for an early Great Divergence. It is important, then, that the low silver
wages in Asia cannot be explained away as a purely monetary phenomenon.
One potential explanation for higher silver wages in Europe would be the
inflow of precious metals from the New World during the sixteenth century. It might
be expected on quantity theory of money grounds that this would lead to higher prices
and wages without any real effects on the standard of living. As is well known, there
was a substantial price inflation in Europe during the sixteenth century, which some
writers have indeed attributed to the bullion flows (Hamilton, 1934; Braudel and
Spooner, 1967). However, on closer examination, it is clear that bullion flows do not
provide an adequate explanation of the much higher silver wages in Europe compared
with Asia, since much of the bullion flowed to the East, both directly via the
Philippines and indirectly via Europe (Barrett, 1990). Rather, we see these high silver
wages as reflecting economic development. This becomes clear when we consider
regional patterns within Europe, since although prices converged, silver wages
diverged.
Looking first at the issue of price convergence, we know that although the
bullion flows entered Europe through Spain, price levels rose by similar amounts in
most European countries (Abel, 1980: 116-120).
4
This is consistent with the classical
price-specie-flow mechanism, with an initial increase in Spanish prices leading to a
4
Hence the similar regional pattern in Tables 1 and 3.
22
reduction in exports and an increase in imports, and hence to a Spanish balance of
payments deficit. Since a Spanish balance of payments deficit meant an outflow of
bullion from Spain, this meant also a rise in the price level in the bullion receiving
countries (Craig and Fisher, 2000: 70-71). Following criticisms concerning the timing
of bullion flows and inflation in particular countries, the argument has been
reformulated in terms of the monetary approach to the balance of payments (Flynn,
1978; Frenkel and Johnson, 1976). In this approach, the initial impact of the
inflationary monetary shock in Spain was transmitted abroad via the law of one price,
which raised the demand for money irrespective of the bullion flows.
Second, turning to the issue of wage divergence, we have seen that while
prices rose along the same trend in all European countries, Spain lost its position as
the high silver wage country, while England saw the biggest long run gains. This
suggests that the shift of silver wage leadership from southern Europe to northwestern
Europe reflected real economic forces rather than monetary forces.
5
Hence the
development gradient within Europe is broadly captured by the pattern of silver
wages. Within this framework, India and China look much more like the stagnating
parts of southern or central and eastern Europe, than the developing parts of
northwestern Europe.
2. Explaining the silver wage gap
It is well known that there is a tendency for both wages and prices to be higher in
developed economies, so that international comparison of wages at the official
exchange rate gives a misleading impression of the gap in living standards between
23
developed and less developed countries (Balassa, 1964; Samuelson, 1964). As a result
of this, wages and per capita incomes are usually compared on a purchasing power
parity (PPP) adjusted basis, taking account of the prices of consumer goods in the
countries being compared (Kravis et al., 1978a). Development economists see the
relationship between the PPP-converted and the exchange rate converted levels of per
capita income as conditioned upon a number of real factors affecting the structure of
the economy (Kravis et al., 1978b; Bhagwati, 1984; Clague, 1985). We see the
relationship between grain wages and silver wages on a comparative basis as related
to these same structural characteristics.
The key results of the Balassa-Samuelson approach to price level differences
can be shown most simply in a two-country Ricardian model, with constant returns to
the single factor of production, labor. Applying the model to the early modern
international economy, we assume that grain is non-tradable internationally, reflecting
the fact that grain was bulky and costly to transport. Thus grain prices were not
equalized between Europe and Asia. On the other hand, commodities such as cloth
and bullion were widely traded internationally, with arbitrage tending to equalize
prices between countries.
6
If the relative prices of all tradable goods are the same in
both countries, we can aggregate and consider them to be a single good, with units
being chosen so that the price of one unit of each tradable good is the same.
7
Here we
5
This point can be traced back to Adam Smiths [1776: 218-219, 256] digression on silver. We are
grateful to George Grantham for alerting us to this illustrious precedent for our argument.
6
Allen (2003) calculates PPP exchange rates between England and the Yangzi delta around 1800 at
18.32 for cloth and 10.03 for grain at a time when the exchange rate was around 20 bronze cash per
penny.
7
Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996: 211). Although there were periods of substantial disequilibrium between
Europe and Asia in the gold-silver price ratio, equilibrium was always restored in the long run by
arbitrage (Flynn and Giráldez (2002).
24
set out the main results intuitively, providing a more detailed exposition of the model
in Appendix 1.
Thus there is one international price for the tradable commodity. Furthermore,
since labor is the only factor of production, the silver wage rate in both countries must
equal revenue labor product in the tradable sector, that is, labor productivity
multiplied by the price of the tradable good. Thus the country with higher real labor
productivity in the tradable sector has the higher silver wage, because the price is the
same in the two countries. Finally, since wages are equalized between sectors within
each economy, this will also be the wage in the non-tradable sector. Again, since
labor is the only factor of production, the price of the non tradable good must equal
the silver wage rate divided by labor productivity in the non-tradable sector. Hence
the price of the non-tradable commodity depends negatively on labor productivity in
the non-tradable sector and positively on labor productivity in the tradable sector
(since this makes for higher silver wages).
A more sophisticated version of this analysis which allows for many distinct
tradable goods has been developed by Dornbusch, Fischer and Samuelson (1977).
8
The model allows for a continuum of tradable goods, which are arranged in terms of
relative labor productivities, with good 0 having the highest relative labor
productivity for the home country and good 1 having the lowest relative labor
productivity. The marginal tradable good is that which both countries are competitive
in producing. Thus the relative silver wages must equal the relative labor
productivities in the production of this marginal tradable good. The country which has
8
Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996: 236-243) provide a clear exposition.
25
higher productivity in the production of this marginal tradable good will have higher
silver wages. This model also shows clearly the principle of comparative advantage
a country will export the good where its relative productivity is high even though its
absolute productivity may well be lower than that of the other country. Thus Indias
export of cotton textiles is a reflection of comparative advantage, and not of an
absolute superiority in productivity.
Countries in northwestern Europe had high silver wages, while Asia had low
silver wages. These lower silver wages reflected lower productivity in the tradable
sector.
9
Asian countries produced cheaper grain as a result of lower silver wages, so
that grain wages were almost as high as in northwestern Europe. This means that we
cannot infer equal levels of economic development in parts of Asia and Europe from
observations based on grain wages alone. When silver wages indicate a much higher
command of European wages over traded goods, and levels of urbanization suggest
higher levels of production of non-agricultural goods, it is difficult to avoid the
conclusion that north western Europe was more developed and living standards were
higher.
VI. CONCLUSIONS
This paper has attempted a quantitative assessment of the recent claims of Pomeranz
(2000) and other world historians, that the Great Divergence between Europe and
Asia occurred only after 1800. An examination of data on wages and prices on the
two continents suggests that the prosperous parts of Asia between 1500 and 1800 look
similar to the stagnating southern, central and eastern parts of Europe rather than the
26
developing northwestern parts. In India and China, grain wages were comparable to
those in northwestern Europe, but silver wages were substantially lower. This is
exactly the pattern observed in the less developed parts of Europe. Essentially, then,
world historians are generalizing the findings of the long-running debate over the
standard of living in Europe to encompass the continent of Asia. It is now widely
accepted following the work of Crafts and Harley (1992) that British economic
growth during the Industrial Revolution was substantially slower than was once
thought, which means that gains in the standard of living were slower to materialize
for the masses. We know now that in northwestern Europe (1) the amount of food
consumed by laborers was slow to rise (2) gains in living standards occurred primarily
through the falling relative price of manufactured goods. However, there is no
revisionist school of European economic history claiming that Poland or Spain were
as likely as Britain to have an Industrial Revolution at the end of the eighteenth
century, and it is no more appropriate to make such a claim for the Yangzi delta
region of China or for southern India.
It is important not to forget that the revisionist work of Crafts and Harley
(1992) had another strand, emphasizing structural change. In addition to highlighting
the modest nature of the growth acceleration during the Industrial Revolution, Crafts
and Harley (1992) pointed out that the extent of the shift of labor out of agriculture in
Britain was more radical than had previously been thought, and also occurred earlier
than was once thought. Generalizing this beyond the British experience, a key feature
of the pattern of development in northwestern Europe was a structural shift out of
agriculture, accompanied by an extensive urbanization. The existence of sufficient
9
It is likely that before the Industrial Revolution this European productivity advantage in tradables
27
grain to feed the population at a reasonable standard of living in southern, central and
eastern Europe was the result of a high share of the economys resources being
devoted to agriculture, and this shows up in relatively low levels of urbanization.
Similarly, in Asia, the high grain wages of the most prosperous parts of India and
China can be attributed to the high share of agriculture in economic activity,
combined with the natural advantage of the high yield of rice relative to wheat. This is
a long way from the development of a large, specialized, high value added structure
above the subsistence agrarian system that characterized northwest European
countries such as Britain and the Netherlands. The Great Divergence between
Europe and Asia, in other words, was already well underway before 1800.
arose from services such as distribution and finance as much as from production methods in
manufacturing (Greif, 2000; Kuran, 2003).
28
APPENDIX 1: A MODEL OF THE SILVER WAGE GAP
Consider a two-country world, with a single factor of production, labor. We assume
one non-tradable commodity (grain) and a single tradable good As a result of
arbitrage, there is one international price p
T
for the tradable good measured in the
common unit of account, silver, so that:
TT
i
pp = (1)
where the superscript T indicates the tradable good and the subscript i indicates the
two countries, Asia and Europe (i=A, E)
With a single factor of production, labor, the silver wage in the two countries is given
by:
T
i
T
i
pw
α
= (2)
where
T
i
α
is labor productivity in the tradable sector of country i. Hence the relatively
low silver wage in Asia must reflect low productivity in the tradable goods sector.
Since wages are equalized between sectors within each economy, the wage in the
tradable sector is also the wage in the non-tradable sector. The price of the non-
tradable commodity is thus equal to the silver wage divided by the level of labor
productivity in the non-tradable sector:
N
i
i
N
i
w
p
α
= (3)
where the superscript N indicates the non-tradable good and
N
i
α
is labor productivity
in the non-tradable sector of country i. Substituting for wages from (2), we obtain:
N
i
TT
i
N
i
p
p
α
α
= (4)
Hence the price of the non-tradable commodity is reduced by high labor productivity
in the non-tradable sector as well as increased by high labor productivity in the
tradable sector.
The grain wage is the silver wage divided by the price of the non-tradable commodity
in each country. Rearranging equation (3), we have:
N
i
N
i
i
p
w
α
= (5)
Hence differences in grain wages reflect only labor productivity differences in non-
tradable production, and do not depend on other factors such as labor productivity
differences in tradable production.
Finally, consider the real consumption wage in the two countries. Assume that the
consumption price is given by the weighted geometric average of the prices of the
traded and non-traded commodities, with a weight of
β
on the latter, and with
0 <
β
< 1 (Obstfeld and Rogoff, 1996: 211). Making the relevant substitutions, we
obtain:
()( )
)1(
ββ
αα
=
N
i
T
i
i
i
p
w
(6)
29
If grain wages are roughly equal in the two countries (i.e.
N
E
N
A
αα
= ), but silver wages
are higher in Europe, this implies that the real consumption wage is lower in Asia, by
a factor which depends on the weight
β
.
The model can be generalized to allow for many distinct tradable goods. Dornbusch,
Fischer and Samuelson (1977) consider such a Ricardian model with a continuum of
tradable goods (see Obstfeld and Rogoff, 1996: 236-243 for an exposition). Let
j
A
j
E
αα
/ denote relative labor productivity in good j. Arrange these goods in order of
decreasing relative labor productivity. Let * denote the index of the marginal tradable
good, i.e. the good that can be produced in both countries. Equation (2) applies where
the productivities relate to the marginal tradable good. That is, the silver wages are
now given by
**
ii
pw
α
= (7)
The rest of the analysis, including the determination of non-tradable prices is the same
as with two goods, given this determination of silver wages.
30
TABLE 1: Silver wages of unskilled and skilled building workers in Europe,
1500-1849 (grams of silver per day)
A. Unskilled laborers
1500-
49
1550-
99
1600-
49
1650-
99
1700-
49
1750-
99
1800-
49
Northwestern Europe
London 3.2 4.6 7.1 9.7 10.5 11.5 17.7
Southern England 2.5 3.4 4.1 5.6 7.0 8.3 14.6
Amsterdam 3.1 4.7 7.2 8.5 8.9 9.2 9.2
Antwerp 3.0 5.9 7.6 7.1 6.9 6.9 7.7
Paris 2.8 5.5 6.6 6.9 5.1 5.2 9.9
Southern Europe
Valencia 4.2 6.6 8.8 6.9 5.7 5.1 --
Madrid -- 6.3 8.0 -- 5.1 5.3 8.0
Milan -- -- 5.9 4.1 3.2 2.9 3.1
Florence 2.9 3.8 4.7 -- -- -- --
Naples 3.3 3.5 5.3 4.8 4.8 3.8 3.8
Central & eastern
Europe
Gdansk 2.1 2.1 3.8 4.3 3.8 3.7 4.8
Warsaw -- 2.5 3.2 2.7 1.9 3.4 4.9
Krakow 1.9 2.9 3.4 2.9 2.2 2.9 2.4
Vienna 2.7 2.6 4.4 3.5 3.2 3.0 2.1
Leipzig -- 1.9 3.5 3.9 3.7 3.1 4.4
Augsburg 2.1 3.1 4.0 4.7 4.2 4.3 --
B. Skilled craftsmen
1500-
49
1550-
99
1600-
49
1650-
99
1700-
49
1750-
99
1800-
49
Northwestern Europe
London 5.0 6.9 11.3 14.5 14.7 17.8 28.9
Southern England 4.2 5.1 6.1 8.4 10.4 12.6 22.0
Amsterdam 4.5 7.0 10.4 11.9 11.7 11.9 12.1
Antwerp 5.2 10.3 12.6 11.8 11.5 11.5 12.8
Paris 4.4 9.0 10.6 11.0 8.2 9.3 16.4
Southern Europe
Valencia 6.5 8.5 10.5 10.3 8.6 7.6 --
Madrid 6.2 12.5 20.1 15.1 11.6 10.7 16.5
Milan -- -- 10.5 8.0 6.1 5.4 6.2
Florence 5.3 7.5 10.6 -- -- -- --
Naples 6.8 5.5 7.8 -- 5.9 5.7 6.6
Central & eastern
Europe
Gdansk 2.8 4.7 6.4 7.7 6.7 5.2 8.0
Warsaw -- 3.6 5.6 4.3 5.3 7.4 10.9
Krakow 3.8 5.2 4.2 4.1 3.3 3.8 5.2
Vienna 4.0 3.9 5.5 5.2 4.8 4.8 3.2
Leipzig 2.9 3.3 6.8 7.0 6.2 5.0 6.7
Augsburg 3.5 4.2 5.4 6.5 6.0 5.4 5.8
Source: Allen (2001: 416).
31
TABLE 2: Grain wages of unskilled and skilled building workers in Europe,
1500-1849 (kilograms of grain per day)
A. Unskilled laborers
1500-
49
1550-
99
1600-
49
1650-
99
1700-
49
1750-
99
1800-
49
Wheat
Southern England 10.1 6.3 4.0 5.4 8.0 7.0 8.6
Antwerp 8.8 7.2 7.7 7.4 9.8 9.6 --
Paris 6.8 4.9 6.0 7.2 7.2 6.0 8.4
Valencia/Madrid 10.7 7.4 6.3 7.6 8.6 4.8 --
Florence/Milan 4.7 3.4 4.4 6.1 5.2 3.3 2.8
Rye
Amsterdam 10.3 8.6 11.5 13.3 17.8 14.0 10.7
Krakow 48.7 27.9 15.7 18.7 22.7 23.0 --
Vienna 18.6 7.6 9.9 9.0 8.0 7.0 3.1
Leipzig/Augsburg 9.6 5.6 6.0 9.5 8.4 6.1 5.8
B. Skilled craftsmen
1500-
49
1550-
99
1600-
49
1650-
99
1700-
49
1750-
99
1800-
49
Wheat
Southern England 16.9 9.4 6.9 8.0 11.8 10.6 13.0
Antwerp 15.3 12.6 12.7 12.2 16.3 16.1 --
Paris 10.7 8.0 9.6 11.5 11.5 10.8 13.9
Valencia/Madrid 16.4 12.0 11.5 13.9 16.1 8.5 --
Florence/Milan 8.6 6.8 8.8 11.8 9.9 6.2 5.6
Rye
Amsterdam 15.0 12.8 16.6 18.7 23.4 18.1 14.1
Krakow 97.4 50.0 19.4 26.5 34.0 30.2 --
Vienna 27.6 11.5 12.4 13.4 12.0 11.2 4.7
Leipzig/Augsburg 14.6 8.4 9.7 14.9 13.0 8.5 8.3
Sources: Wages from Table 1 deflated by grain prices from Abel (1980: 304-305);
Additional information on grain prices in Spain from Hamilton (1934; 1947).
32
TABLE 3: Real consumption wages of European unskilled building laborers
(London 1500-49 = 100)
1500-
49
1550-
99
1600-
49
1650-
99
1700-
49
1750-
99
1800-
49
Northwestern Europe
London 100 85 80 96 110 99 98
Amsterdam 97 74 92 98 107 98 79
Antwerp 98889388928882
Paris 62605960565165
Southern Europe
Valencia 79 63 62 53 51 41 --
Madrid -- 56 51 -- 58 42 --
Florence/Milan 62535751473526
Naples 73 54 69 -- 88 50 33
Central & eastern
Europe
Gdansk 78 50 69 72 73 61 40
Warsaw -- 75 66 72 45 64 82
Krakow 67 74 65 67 58 63 40
Vienna 88 60 61 63 61 50 27
Leipzig --343557534453
Augsburg 625039635550 --
Source: Derived from Allen (2001: 428).
TABLE 4: Urban shares of the population in Europe, 1500-1850 (%)
1500 1600 1700 1800 1850
England & Wales 3.1 5.8 13.3 20.3 40.8
Netherlands 15.8 24.3 33.6 28.8 29.5
Belgium 21.1 18.8 24.3 18.9 20.5
France 4.2 5.9 9.2 8.8 14.5
Spain 6.1 11.4 9.0 11.1 17.3
Italy 12.4 15.1 13.2 14.6 20.3
Poland 0.0 0.4 0.5 2.4 9.3
Austria/Bohemia 1.7 2.1 3.9 5.2 6.7
Germany 3.2 4.1 4.8 5.5 10.8
Europe 5.6 7.6 9.2 10.0 16.7
Note: Based on the percentage of the population living in towns of at least 10,000
inhabitants.
Source: Derived from de Vries (1984: 30, 36, 45).
33
TABLE 5: Indian silver and grain wages, 1595-1874
A. Northern and western India
Silver wage
(grams per day)
Wheat grain wage
(kg per day)
Rice grain wage
(kg per day)
Unskilled Skilled Unskilled Skilled Unskilled Skilled
1595 0.67 1.62 5.2 12.6 3.1 7.5
1616 0.86 3.0 2.4
1623 1.08 3.8 2.9
1637 1.08 2.37 3.8 8.3 2.9 6.5
1640 1.29 4.5 3.5
1690 1.40 4.3
1874 1.79 5.27 2.5 7.5
B. Southern India
Silver wage
(grams per day)
Rice grain wage
(kg per day)
Unskilled Skilled Unskilled Skilled
1610-13 1.15 5.7
1600-50 1.15 3.2
1680 1.44 2.44 3.9 6.9
1741-50 1.49 2.1
1750 (3.02) (7.56) (4.2) (10.5)
1779 0.86 1.1
1790 1.44 1.8
Sources and notes:
Northern and western India: Silver wages: 1595: Daily wages for unskilled laborers
and skilled craftsmen in Agra from $E
¶OFazl [1595: 123, 132-133, 145-146, 155,
159, 161-162, 235-236, 261-264, 297], following Desai (1978: 56-57).
1616, 1623, 1690: Daily wage for unskilled laborers in Surat derived from monthly
wages of peons from Habib (1978: 379).
1637: Daily wage for unskilled laborers in Agra derived from monthly wages of
peons from Habib (1978: 378). Daily wages for skilled workers in Agra from
Mukerjee (1967: 24, 48).
1640: Daily wage for unskilled laborers in Surat derived from monthly wages of
peons from Foster (1906-27, volume 1634-36: 151).
1874: Daily wages for unskilled and skilled laborers in Agra from Moosvi (1987:
335).
Conversion rates from rupees to silver: 1 rupee was worth 10.78 grams of pure silver
(Habib, 1978: 360-361; Chaudhuri, 1978: 471).
Grain prices: 1595: Grain prices from $E
¶OFazl [1595: 65], noting that a man of
1595 was 55.32 lb (Heston, 1977: 393). Rice price 110.62 lb per rupee, wheat price
184.36 lb per rupee.
1616, 1623, 1637, 1640: Grain prices from Moreland (1923: 171) at 65 lbs per rupee
for rice and 82.5 lb per rupee for wheat.
1690: Wheat price from Habib (1978: 373) at 72.40 lb per rupee.
1874: Wheat price from Moosvi (1987: 335) at 33.73 lb per rupee.
Southern India:
Silver wages: 1610-13: Daily wages for unskilled laborers in Golconda based on
wages of servants in Dutch factory from Arasaratnam (1986: 342).
34
1600-50: Daily wages for unskilled laborers in East Godavari Delta based on earnings
of weavers from Brennig (1986: 348).
1680: Daily wages for unskilled and skilled laborers in East Godavari Delta based on
earnings of skilled and unskilled weavers from Brennig (1986: 349).
1741-50: Daily wages for unskilled laborers in Madras based on wages of laborers in
scavenging services from Arasaratnam (1986: 343).
1750: Daily wages of unskilled and skilled laborers in Cuddalore based on earnings of
calico weavers from Parthasarathi (1998: 84, 97).
1779: Daily wages of unskilled laborers in Cuddalore based on earnings of weavers
from Arasaratnam (1980: 269-270).
1790: Daily wages for unskilled labor in Cuddalore based on weavers earnings from
Arasaratnam (1980: 269-270) and Ramaswamy, (1985:153)
Conversion rates from pagodas to rupees: East India Company standard rate of 3.2
rupees per pagoda, apart from during the period 1678-1705, when it was 4 rupees per
1 pagoda (Chaudhuri, 1978: 471).
Grain prices: 1610-13: Price of rice at 117 lb per rupee from Arasaratnam (1986: 336-
337).
1600-50, 1680: Rice price 65 lb per rupee from Arasaratnam (1980: 270)
1741-50, 1750: Rice price at 33 lb per rupee from Arasaratnam (1980: 270).
1779, 1790: Rice price at 30 lb per rupee from Arasaratnam (1980: 270).
TABLE 6: An Anglo-Indian comparison of the daily wages of unskilled laborers,
1550-1849
A. Silver wages (grams of silver per day)
Date Southern
England
India Indian wage as %
of English wage
1550-99 3.4 0.7 21
1600-49 4.1 1.1 27
1650-99 5.6 1.4 25
1700-49 7.0 1.5 21
1750-99 8.3 1.2 14
1800-49 14.6 1.8 12
B. Grain wages (kilograms of grain per day)
England India Indian wage as %
Date (wheat) (wheat) (rice, on wheat
equivalent basis)
of English wage
1550-99 6.3 5.2 83
1600-49 4.0 3.8 95
1650-99 5.4 4.3 80
1700-49 8.0 3.2 40
1750-99 7.0 2.3 33
1800-49 8.6 2.5 29
Sources: Tables 1, 2, 5.
Note: Wheat equivalence of rice obtained on calorific basis, multiplying rice grain
wage by 1.5 (Parthasarathi, 1998: 83).
35
TABLE 7: Daily wage of hired farm laborers in the Yangzi delta, 1573-1850
Late Ming
1573-1644
Mid Qing
1736-1850
Money wage (taels) 0.04 0.033
Silver wage (grams of silver) 1.5 1.2
Grain wage (kg of rice) 3.0 1.5
Notes and sources: Late Ming: Money wage from Li (1998: 94), converted to silver
wage using 1 tael = 37.5 grams of silver, from von Glahn (1996: 133). Money wage
converted to grain wage using rice price of 1 tael per shi of 75 kg from Li (1998: 210,
fn 1). Mid Qing: Money wage from Pomeranz (2000: 319-320), converted to silver
wage using 1 tael = 37.5 grams of silver, from von Glahn (1996: 133). Money wage
converted to grain wage using rice price of 1.67 tael per shi of 75 kg from Pomeranz
(2000: 319).
TABLE 8: An Anglo-Chinese comparison of the daily wage of unskilled laborers,
1550-1849
A. Silver wages (grams of silver per day)
Date Southern
England
Yangzi
delta
Chinese wage as %
of English wage
1550-1649 3.8 1.5 39
1750-1849 11.5 1.2 10
B. Grain wages (kilograms of grain per day)
England Yangzi delta Chinese wage as %
Date (wheat) (rice) (rice, on wheat
equivalent basis)
of English wage
1550-1649 5.2 3.0 4.5 87
1750-1849 7.8 1.5 2.3 29
Sources: Tables 1, 2, 7.
Note: Wheat equivalence of rice obtained on calorific basis, multiplying rice grain
wage by 1.5 (Parthasarathi, 1998: 83).
36
TABLE 9: Urban shares of the population in China and Europe, 618-1820 (%)
Tang
618-906
Song
960-1279
Ming
1368-1644
Early Qing
1644-1736
Early 19
th
century
China
All urban 4.7 5.2 6.5 6.8 5.9
Cities > 10,000 3.0 3.7 4.9 6.0 3.8
Europe
Cities > 10,000 -- -- 7.6 9.2 10.0
Source: China: Derived from Rozman (1973: 102, 279-283); Europe: Table 4.
Note: Urbanization ratio for cities of at least 10,000 inhabitants derived from
Rozmans level 1-4 cities.
TABLE 10: Regional variations in the Chinese urbanization ratio in the mid-19
th
century (%)
All urban Cities >10,000
Northern China
Shandong 4.4 2.6
Shanxi 4.0 2.0
Henan 5.0 2.2
Northwestern China
Shaanxi 7.3 4.5
Gansu 4.3 2.3
East central China
Anhui 4.0 1.9
Jiangsu 7.4 5.6
Zheijiang 6.1 4.1
Central China
Hubei 6.0 4.0
Hunan 5.2 2.8
Jiangxi 6.3 3.8
Southeastern China
Fujian 8.2 5.3
Guangdong 6.7 5.0
Guangxi 6.1 3.3
Southwestern China
Guizhou 5.8 3.3
Yunnan 4.4 2.5
Sichuan 6.0 3.6
Source: Derived from Rozman (1973: 205, 213, 218, 231, 239, 247).
37
REFERENCES
Abel, Wilhelm (1980). Agricultural Fluctuations in Europe: From the Thirteenth to
the Twentieth Centuries. New York: St Martins.
$E
¶OFazl [1595] (1927). 7KH ¶ Q±L$NEDU . Translated into English by
H.Blochman. Delhi: Low Price Publications.
Allen, Robert C. (2000). Economic Structure and Agricultural Productivity in
Europe, 1300-1800. European Review of Economic History 4, 1-26.
Allen, Robert C. (2001). The Great Divergence in European Wages and Prices from
the Middle Ages to the First World War. Explorations in Economic History
38, 411-447.
Allen, Robert C. (2003). Agricultural Productivity and Rural Incomes in England
and the Yangtze Delta. Nuffield College, Oxford.
Arasaratnam, S. (1980). Weavers, Merchants and Company: The Handloom Industry
in Southeastern India 1750-1790. Indian Economic and Social History
Review 17, 257-281.
Arasaratnam, S. (1986). Merchants, Companies and Commerce on the Coromandel
Coast, 1650-1740. Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Bairoch, Paul (1976). Population urbaine et Taille des villes en Europe de 1600 à
1970. Revue d’Histoire Économique et Sociale 54, 304-335.
Balassa, Bela (1964). The Purchasing-Power Parity Doctrine: A Reappraisal.
Journal of Political Economy 76, 584-596.
Barrett, Ward (1990). World Bullion Flows. In The Rise of Merchant Empires:
Long-Distance trade in the Early Modern World, 1350-1750, edited by James
D. Tracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 224-254.
Beveridge, William (1939). Prices and Wages in England from the Twelfth to the
Nineteenth Century, Vol. I, Price Tables: Mercantile Era. London: Longmans,
Green.
Bhagwati, Jagdish N. (1984). Why are Services Cheaper in Poor Countries?
Economic Journal 94, 279-286.
Blake, Stephen P. (1987). The Structure of Monetary Exchange in North India: The
provinces of Agra, Delhi and Lahore in 1600. In The Imperial Monetary
System of Mughal India, edited by John F. Richards. Oxford: Oxford
University Press, 100-136.
Braudel, Fernand P. and Frank Spooner (1967). Prices in Europe from 1450 to
1750. In The Cambridge Economic History of Europe, Vol. IV: The Economy
of Expanding Europe in the Sixteenth and Seventeenth Centuries, edited by
Edwin E. Rich and Charles H. Wilson. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 374-486.
Brenner, Robert and Christopher Isett(2002). Englands Divergence from Chinas
Yangzi Delta: Property Relations, Microeconomics, and Patterns of
Development. Journal of Asian Studies 61, 609-662.
Brennig, Joseph (1986). Textile Producers and Production in Late Seventeenth-
Century Coromandel. Indian Economic and Social History Review 23, 333-
356.
Broadberry, Stephen N. (1998). How did the United States and Germany Overtake
Britain? A Sectoral Analysis of Comparative Productivity Levels, 1870-1990.
Journal of Economic History 58, 375-407.
Broadberry, Stephen and Sayantan Ghosal (2002). From the Counting House to the
Modern Office: Explaining Anglo-American Productivity Differences in
Services, 1870-1990." Journal of Economic History 62, 967-998.
38
Broadberry, Stephen and Sayantan Ghosal (2003). Technology, Organisation and
Productivity Performance in Services: Lessons from Britain and the United
States Since 1870. Department of Economics, University of Warwick.
http://www2.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/economics/staff/faculty/broadberry/wp/ser
vmod2.pdf
Chaudhuri, Kirti N. (1978). The Trading World of Asia and the English East India
Company, 1660-1760. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Chuan, Han-sheng and Richard A. Kraus (1975). Mid-Ching Rice Markets and
Trade: An Essay in Price History. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Clague, Christopher K. (1985). A Model of Real National Price Levels. Southern
Economic Journal 51, 998-1017.
Clarkson, Leslie A. (1985). Proto-Industrialization: The First Phase of
Industrilaization? London: Macmillan.
Coleman, Donald C. (1983). Proto-industrialization: A Concept Too Many.
Economic History Review 36, 435-448.
Crafts, Nicholas F.R. and C. Knick Harley (1992). Output Growth and the British
Industrial Revolution: A Restatement of the Crafts-Harley View. Economic
History Review 45, 703-730.
Craig, Lee A. and Douglas Fisher (2000). The European Macroeconomy: Growth,
Integration and Cycles 1500-1913. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Desai, Ashok V. (1972). Population and Standards of Living in Akbars Time.
Indian Economic and Social History Review 9, 43-62.
Desai, Ashok V. (1978). Population and Standards of Living in Akbars Time A
Second Look. Indian Economic and Social History Review 15, 53-79.
Dornbusch, Rudiger, Stanley Fischer and Paul A. Samulelson (1977). Comparative
Advantage, Trade and Payments in a Ricardian Model with a Continuum of
Goods. American Economic Review 67, 823-39.
Foster, William (1906-27). The English Factories in India: A Calendar of Documents
(13 Volumes). British Library, London.
Frank, Andre Gunder (1998), ReOrient: The Silver Age in Asia and the World
Economy. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Flynn, Dennis O. (1978). A New Perspective on the Spanish Price Revolution: The
Monetary Approach to the Balance of Payments. Explorations in Economic
History 15, 388-406.
Flynn, Dennis and A. Giráldez (2002). Cycles of Silver: Global Economic Unity
through the Mid-Eighteenth Century. Journal of World History 13, 391-427.
Frenkel, Jacob and Johnson, Harry G. (1976). The Monetary Approach to the Balance
of Payments. London: Allen and Unwin.
Gamble, Sidney D. (1943). Daily Wages of Unskilled Chinese Laborers 1807-1902.
Far Eastern Quarterly 3, 41-73.
Glaeser, Edward L., Hedi D. Kallal, José A. Scheinkman and Andrei Shleifer (1992).
Growth in Cities. Journal of Political Economy 100, 1126-1152.
von Glahn, Richard (1996). Fountain of Fortune: Money and Monetary Policy in
China, 1000-1700. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Greif, Avner (2000). The Fundamental Problem of Exchange: A Research Agenda in
Historical Institutional Analysis. European Review of Economic History 4,
251-284.
Habib, Irfan (1978). Monetary System and Prices. In The Cambridge Economic
History of India, Volume 1: c.1200 c.1750, edited by Tapan Raychaudhuri
and Irfan Habib. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 360-381.
39
Habib, Irfan (1999). The Agrarian System of Mughal India. Delhi: Oxford University
Press.
Hambly, Gavin R.G. and Burton Stein (1978). Towns and Cities. In The Cambridge
Economic History of India, Volume 1: c.1200 c.1750, edited by Tapan
Raychaudhuri and Irfan Habib. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 434-
457.
Hamilton, Earl J. (1934). American Treasure and the Price Revolution in Spain, 1501-
1650. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Hamilton, Earl J. (1947). War and Prices in Spain, 1651-1800. Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press.
Henderson, Vernon, Ari Kuncoro and Matt Turner (1995). Industrial Development in
Cities. Journal of Political Economy 103, 1067-1090.
Heston, Alan W. (1977). The Standard of Living in Akbars Time: A Comment.
Indian Economic and Social History Review 14, 391-396.
Hoffman, Philip T., David S. Jacks, Patricia A. Levin and Peter H. Lindert (2002).
Real Inequality in Europe since 1500. Journal of Economic History 62, 322-
355.
Huang, Philip (1990). The Peasant Family and Rural Development in the Yangzi
Delta, 1350-1988. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
Huang, Philip C.C. (2002). Development or Involution in Eighteenth-Century Britain
and China? A Review of Kenneth Pomeranzs The Great Divergence: China,
Europe and the Making of the Modern World Economy. Journal of Asian
Studies 61, 501-538.
Jacobs, Jane (1969). The Economy of Cities. New York: Vintage.
Kravis, IrvingB., Alan Heston and Robert Summers (1978a). International
Comparisons of Real Product and Purchasing Power. Baltimore: Johns
Hopkins University Press.
Kravis, IrvingB., Alan Heston and Robert Summers (1978b). Real Per Capita
Income for More than One Hundred Countries. Economic Journal 88, 215-
242.
Kuran, Timur (2003). The Islamic Commercial Crisis: Institutional Roots of
Economic Underdevelopment in the Middle East. Journal of Economic
History 63, 414-446.
Li, Bhozong (1998). Agricultural Development in Jiangnan, 1620-1850. London:
Macmillan.
Maddison, Angus (1998). Chinese Economic Performance in the Long Run. Paris:
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.
Marshall, Alfred [1920] (1977). Principles of Economics, (8th Edition). London:
Macmillan, Reprint.
Matthews, Robin C.O., Charles H. Feinstein and John C. Odling-Smee (1982). British
Economic Growth, 1856-1973. Oxford: Clarendon.
Mendels, Franklin F. (1972). Proto-industrialization: The First Phase of the
Industrialization Process. Journal of Economic History 32, 241-261.
Moosvi, Shireen (1973). Production, Consumption and Population in Akbars Time.
Indian Economic and Social History Review 10, 181-195.
Moosvi, Shireen (1977). Note on Professor Hestons Standard of Living in Akbars
Time A Comment. Indian Economic and Social History Review 14, 397-
401.
Moosvi, Shireen (1987). The Economy of the Mughal Empire c.1595. Delhi: Oxford
University Press.
40
Moreland, William H. (1923). From Akbar to Aurangzeb: A Study in Indian
Economic History. London: Macmillan.
Mukerjee, Radhakamal (1967). The Economic History of India, 1600-1800.
Allahabad.
Obstfeld, Maurice and Kenneth Rogoff (1996). Foundations of International
Economics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Parthasarathi, Prasannan (1998). Rethinking Wages and Competitiveness in the
Eighteenth Century: Britain and South India. Past and Present 158, 79-109.
Parthasarathi, Prasannan (2001). The Transition to a Colonial Economy: Weavers,
Merchants and Kings in South India, 1720-1800. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Perkins, Dwight H. (1969). Agricultural Development in China 1368-1968.
Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.
Phelps Brown, Henry and Sheila V. Hopkins (1981). A Perspective of Wages and
Prices. London: Methuen.
Pomeranz, Kenneth (2000). The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Making of
the Modern World Economy. Princeton: NJ: Princeton University Press.
Ramaswamy, Vijaya (1985). Textile Weavers in Medieval South India. Delhi: Oxford
University Press.
Rozman, Gilbert (1973). Urban Networks in Ching China and Tokugawa Japan.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Samuelson, Paul A. (1964). Theoretical Notes on trade Problems. Review of
Economics and Statistics 46, 145-54.
Smith, Adam [1776] (1976). An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of
Nations. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Voth, Hans-Joachim (1998). Time and Work in Eighteenth-Century London.
Journal of Economic History 58, 29-58.
de Vries, Jan (1984). European Urbanization 1500-1800. London: Methuen.
de Vries, Jan (1993). Between Purchasing Power and the World of Goods:
Understanding the Household Economy in Early Modern Europe. In
Consumption and the World of Goods, edited by John Brewer and Roy Porter.
London: Routledge, 85-132.
de Vries, Jan (1994). The Industrial Revolution and the Industrious Revolution.
Journal of Economic History 54, 249-270.
Wang, Yeh-Chien (1972). The Secular Trend of Prices during the Ching Period
(1644-1911). Journal of the Institute of Chinese Studies of the Chinese
University of Hong Kong 5, 347-71.
Wang, Yeh-Chien (1992). Secular Trends of Rice Prices in the Yangzi Delta, 1638-
1935. In Chinese History in Economic Perspective, edited by Thomas G.
Rawski and Lillian M. Li. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 35-
68.
van Zanden, Jan Luiten (1999). Wages and the Standard of Living in Europe, 1500-
1800. European Review of Economic History 3, 175-97.