Retail payment systems in
New Zealand
Issues Paper
October 2016
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
2
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
Contents
Contents ........................................................................................................................................ 2
How to have your say .................................................................................................................... 3
Glossary of terms .......................................................................................................................... 5
Executive Summary ....................................................................................................................... 6
1. Introduction ........................................................................................................................ 11
Structure of this Issues Paper ...................................................................................... 11 1.1
What are retail payment systems? ............................................................................. 12 1.2
Objectives .................................................................................................................... 12 1.3
Regulation of retail payments in New Zealand ........................................................... 13 1.4
2. Payment systems in New Zealand ....................................................................................... 16
Introduction ................................................................................................................ 16 2.1
Parties in the system ................................................................................................... 17 2.2
Types of payment card and the types of transactions ................................................ 18 2.3
Methods of switching .................................................................................................. 20 2.4
Trends in usage of payment options ........................................................................... 21 2.5
Emerging payment methods ....................................................................................... 23 2.6
3. Market business models and resource costs ...................................................................... 27
Switch-to issuer transactions ...................................................................................... 27 3.1
Switch-to-acquirer transactions .................................................................................. 30 3.2
Ancillary relationships ................................................................................................. 44 3.3
Resource costs ............................................................................................................. 45 3.4
4. Issues identified................................................................................................................... 47
Overview ..................................................................................................................... 47 4.1
The interchange business model is resulting in inefficient outcomes in the credit card 4.2
market ..................................................................................................................................... 48
Inefficiencies could develop in the debit market ........................................................ 54 4.3
There is a large gap between the MSFs faced by small and large merchants ............ 62 4.4
Assessment against objectives .................................................................................... 64 4.5
5. Possible next steps .............................................................................................................. 65
Immediate actions ....................................................................................................... 65 5.1
Further work to address the wider policy issues ........................................................ 66 5.2
Recap of questions ...................................................................................................................... 69
Annex 1: International experiences ............................................................................................ 71
Annex 2: The Commerce Commission’s 2009 settlement .......................................................... 77
Annex 3: List of stakeholders ...................................................................................................... 79
Annex 4: Key figures used in this Issues Paper ........................................................................... 80
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
3
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
How to have your say
The Ministry of Business, Innovation and Employment (MBIE) seeks written submissions on the
issues raised in this document by 5pm on Tuesday, 13 December 2016. Questions are posed
throughout the document to guide your submission.
Your submission may respond to any or all of these questions. We also encourage your input
on any other relevant issues. Where possible, please include evidence to support your views,
for example references to independent research, facts and figures, or relevant examples.
You can make your submission:
By sending your submission as a Microsoft Word document to
competition.policy@mbie.govt.nz
By mailing your submission to:
Competition and Consumer Policy
Building, Resources and Markets
Ministry of Business, Innovation & Employment
PO Box 1473
Wellington 6140
New Zealand
Please direct any questions that you have in relation to the submissions process to Steven Sue
on steven.sue@mbie.govt.nz
.
Use of information
The information provided in submissions will be used to inform MBIE’s policy development
process, and will inform advice to Ministers on retail payment systems.
We may contact submitters directly if we require clarification of any matters in submissions.
Submissions are subject to the Official Information Act 1982. MBIE intends to upload PDF
copies of submissions received to MBIE’s website at www.mbie.govt.nz. MBIE will consider you
to have consented to uploading by making a submission, unless you clearly specify otherwise
in your submission.
Please set out clearly with your submission if you have any objection to the release of any
information in the submission, and in particular, which parts you consider should be withheld,
together with the reasons for withholding the information. MBIE will take such objections into
account and will consult with submitters when responding to requests under the Official
Information Act 1982.
If your submission contains any confidential information, please indicate this on the front of
the submission. Any confidential information should be clearly marked within the text. If you
wish to provide a submission containing confidential information, please provide a separate
version excluding the relevant information for publication on our website.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
4
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
Private information
The Privacy Act 1993 establishes certain principles with respect to the collection, use and
disclosure of information about individuals by various agencies, including MBIE. Any personal
information you supply to MBIE in the course of making a submission will only be used for the
purpose of assisting in the development of policy advice in relation to this review. Please
clearly indicate in your submission if you do not wish your name to be included in any
summary of submissions that MBIE may publish.
Permission to reproduce
The copyright owner authorises reproduction of this work, in whole or in part, as long as no
charge is being made for the supply of copies, and the integrity and attribution of the work as
a publication of MBIE is not interfered with in any way.
ISBN 978-0-947524-29-6 (online)
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
5
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
Glossary of terms
Acquirer: An organisation, typically a bank, which provides access to the payment system on behalf of
merchants for the clearing and settlement of funds in a transaction. An acquirer may or may not also be the
bank that provides other services to a merchant, such as lending and deposits.
Cardholder/customer/consumer: Buys goods and services from merchants in exchange for payment.
Card-present transaction: Any transaction where a customer is in the same physical location as the merchant.
Card-not-present transaction: Any transaction made online, over the phone, or in other situations in which a
customer is not in the same physical location as the merchant.
Contactless transaction: Any transaction made using contactless technology (such as Visa PayWave and
MasterCard PayPass) where the customer is in the same physical location as the merchant. Includes card- and
app-based payments.
Customer interface: Either the physical terminal (card-present) or digital customer gateway (card-not-present)
through which the customer makes a payment to a merchant.
Direct entry: A method of transferring funds between bank accounts that does not rely on scheme or
proprietary EFTPOS rails. Also known as account-to-account payments. Can include manual bank transfers,
automatic payments, direct debit transactions, etc.
Interchange fee: A payment made from an acquirer to an issuer (or occasionally the reverse), each time certain
forms of retail payments are made.
Issuer: An organisation, typically a bank, which issues cards and provides debit and/or credit services to
customers.
Merchant: A party that provides goods or services in return for payment. Includes retailers, wholesalers,
utilities companies, and central and local government.
Merchant service fee (MSF): A payment made from a merchant to an acquirer each time certain forms of retail
payments are made.
Proprietary EFTPOS: The ‘traditional’ form of card payment in New Zealand, which utilises mag-stripe
technology. Standards are maintained by Payments New Zealand, but no owneras such.
Resource cost: The economic resources expended by system participants to ‘produce’ a payment. This includes
fraud prevention costs, authorisation and transaction processing costs, and other back-office costs. Excludes
transfers between parties, such as rewards or MSFs.
Scheme: Includes Visa, MasterCard, American Express, and Diners Club. Schemes develop technology and base
product features, and set the commercial model and card system rules. They may issue cards and attract
merchants through banks (open system Visa and MasterCard) or directly (closed system American Express,
Diners Club, etc.). Only relevant for non-proprietary-EFTPOS transactions.
Steering: When a merchant does not accept, or discourages, payment via certain means.
Surcharging: When a merchant charges more to accept payment via certain means.
Switch: Payments infrastructure that sends transaction information to the correct issuer or acquirer
(depending on the type of transaction) so that the funds can be taken from the customer's account and
delivered to the merchant.
Switch-to-acquirer: The process by which information about certain card payments, notably credit cards,
contactless scheme debit, card-not present and international transactions, is sent between institutions.
Attracts interchange (except for closed schemes) and MSFs.
Switch-to-issuer: The process by which information about certain card payments, notably proprietary EFTPOS
and inserted/swiped scheme debit, is sent between institutions. Attracts no interchange fee or MSF.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
6
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
Executive Summary
Overview
1. In February 2016, the Minister of Finance and the Minister of Commerce and Consumer
Affairs commissioned a study into New Zealand’s retail payment system in the context
of:
merchant concerns about increasing fees for the processing of electronic
transactions;
industry developments, including the adoption of new technologies; and
ongoing reforms to the oversight and regulation of retail payment systems in
overseas jurisdictions.
2. In addition to outlining how retail payment systems work in New Zealand, this Issues
Paper looks at the economic outcomes that result from New Zealand’s retail payment
system (as opposed to, for example, financial system stability outcomes which are
considered by the Reserve Bank). It focuses predominantly, but not exclusively, on credit
and debit cards, in reflection of their dominance of retail payments.
3. This Issues Paper was developed by the Ministry of Business, Innovation and
Employment so the views expressed in this paper should be read as the Ministry’s
preliminary views, not necessarily those of the Government.
4. The Government is now wishing to test the Ministry’s analysis with the public. Retail
payment systems are extremely complex and it is important to fully understand the
issues before the Government decides whether to proceed any further. While the
Government is not at the stage of considering options, it is also important to bear in
mind that if we proceed to that stage, any potential solution would need to be tested
against the harm it is designed to address and that all the consequences are taken into
account.
5. For example, some overseas jurisdictions have regulated interchange fees to address the
issues discussed in this Issues Paper. While this approach is designed to address the
issues at hand by reducing the ability of banks to provide generous rewards to
incentivise credit card use, it could also see banks increase annual fees on credit cards to
maintain reward levels, or reduce the generosity of reward programmes. It is therefore
important to understand all of these impacts when considering the issues.
Background
6. Each year consumers make approximately 1.5 billion electronic card transactions,
representing more than $76 billion in expenditure. Transactions made using electronic
cards are responsible for around two thirds of retail trade revenue in core industries,
and this share of retail revenue has been growing steadily compared to other payment
methods such as cash. Within card-based payments, currently around 42 per cent of
transactions (by value) are made using credit cards, 36 per cent using proprietary
EFTPOS, 15 per cent using swiped/inserted scheme debit, and 7 per cent using
contactless scheme debit. While cash remains an important retail currency, New
Zealand has the lowest proportion of cash to GDP in circulation in the world. The
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
7
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
payment card market can be considered to be at saturation, with 93.8 per cent of adults
in possession of and using a debit card.
7. Electronic payments provide a number of key benefits to consumers, merchants (such as
retailers), and government. This includes greater convenience; reduced risk of fraud,
theft, and bad debts; the ability to purchase online; reduced cash-handling costs; greater
certainty of tax revenue; and in the case of credit cards the ability to smooth
consumption over time.
8. We estimate that the inherent ‘resource cost’ of processing card payments each year is
around $950 million, or roughly 1.3 per cent of the value of the $76 billion dollars of
transactions made on payment cards across the economy. This is the economic resource
required to facilitate these transactions. Merchants carry the bulk of the direct costs,
paying an estimated $461 million in merchant service fees in 2015. We expect that these
fees could increase significantly in coming years with rapid uptake of contactless
payment. This could increase the fees paid by another $216 million annually.
9. In preparing this Paper, we asked the following questions:
Are consumers and merchants benefiting from ongoing innovation?
Are card payment systems being used efficiently?
Are consumers and merchants bearing a fair share of the costs?
Issues identified
10. The Ministry has found that the market dynamics suggest cause for concern in both the
credit and debit card markets.
Issue 1: Economic inefficiency in the credit card market
11. We consider that there is economic inefficiency in the credit card market. While credit
cards provide a number of benefits to both consumers and merchants, we estimate that
current market incentives drive at least $45 million per year of additional cost to the
economy through the use of more expensive credit card networks compared to lower
cost EFTPOS networks. This figure focuses on the transactions that are induced by the
incentives in the system, not the ones that are placed on credit cards on the basis of
their inherent credit functionality or their ability to be used overseas. $45 million
represents 5 percent of the total resource cost for processing electronic card payments
in New Zealand, and around 0.13 per cent of the total value of expenditure on credit
cards in the year to March 2016.
Issue 2: Increased prices for all consumers, with only higher-income consumers
benefiting from rewards
12. The costs of merchant service fees are ultimately likely to be passed onto consumers
through the price of goods and services. Some of the cost that is passed on is used to
fund rewards and other inducements for using credit cards. We estimate that merchants
have to increase their prices to all consumers by around $187 million per year to fund
rewards paid to certain credit card users. Because of the way credit card reward
schemes are structured, this leads to an annual regressive cross-subsidy of $59 million
from low-income to high-income households. These costs are ongoing, so they add up
over many years.
13. Issues 1 and 2 are a result of the business model under which credit card schemes
operate. Payment systems are two-sided markets, in that they rely on uptake by both
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
8
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
consumers and merchants to be valuable. At the centre of this business model is the use
of interchange fees, which place charges on merchants and pass them on to the banks
that issue credit cards. Interchange fees allow banks that issue credit cards to incentivise
credit card use, such as through rewards schemes, effectively paying many consumers to
use their credit card instead of the cheaper EFTPOS system. These interchange fees are
then passed onto all consumers (irrespective of the type of card used) through higher
prices because most merchants do not recover those fees through surcharges.
14. Credit card schemes have traditionally operated under this interchange business model,
but there is evidence that the inefficiencies generated are increasing, with recent
competition driving up interchange fees and the value of rewards. We are also seeing
banks “flipping” credit card users to higher cost premium cards that offer higher levels
of rewards. All but the largest merchants hold little bargaining power over these fees,
with consumer demand giving them little choice but to accept payment via credit card.
15. These outcomes are not the result of irrational or anti-competitive behaviour by any
particular party. It is completely rational for credit card holders to maximise usage to
obtain rewards in the presence of distorted price signals. Similarly, the setting of
interchange and use of rewards schemes is perfectly rational profit maximising
behaviour on the part of the schemes and the banks. Despite this individual rationality,
without price signals, this business model results in an inefficient overall outcome.
16. Based on the information available to us, merchants in New Zealand appear to pay
higher fees to accept payment via credit card than merchants in some overseas
countries. New Zealand’s credit interchange fees are roughly comparable to what is paid
in the USA and Canada, where credit interchange is not regulated. However, New
Zealand interchange rates and merchant service fees are significantly higher than those
in regulated environments, such as the European Union and Australia. The overall higher
cost of electronic transactions may be offset to some extent because no charges are
applied to EFTPOS and swiped/inserted scheme debit transactions, which currently
account for around half of all card transactions.
Issue 3: Emerging inefficiency in the debit card market
17. Similar market dynamics are beginning to emerge in the debit card space, with rapid
growth of the market share of scheme debit products in place of New Zealand’s
proprietary EFTPOS system. Contactless and online scheme debit now make up about 15
per cent of the debit card market, up from about two per cent two years ago. New
Zealand is different to many economies in still having a domestic EFTPOS system that
does not charge per-transaction fees to merchants. It is, however, unlikely that such a
model is sustainable when competing with scheme products, regardless of the
underlying efficiency of domestic EFTPOS.
18. The growth of scheme debit products provides many benefits such as additional
security, and the ability to make contactless and online transactions in contrast to
proprietary EFTPOS which has suffered from a sustained lack of investment.
19. Nevertheless, such benefits come with additional cost, as schemes have introduced
interchange fees on contactless (and online) debit transactions, in contrast to
proprietary EFTPOS, which does not attract such fees. We estimate that fees to
merchants on scheme debit transactions could rise by $216 million per year if
contactless usage increases to 60 per cent of debit payments.
20. The imposition of fees in itself is not inherently a problem, given that the lack of fees is a
key reason behind the lack of investment in proprietary EFTPOS. However, as
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
9
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
contactless debit becomes entrenched, we are concerned that the competitive
constraint on fees to merchants currently provided by proprietary EFTPOS will reduce.
This could result in the interchange dynamics we currently see in the credit card market
driving inefficiency and large scale cross-subsidisation in the debit market as well.
Issue 4: Barriers to entry in the debit market
21. We are also concerned about the impact that a scheme-dominated debit market would
have on market entry and expansion. While it is possible for a new entrant to disrupt the
market before full scheme dominance occurs, the interchange model sets up entry and
expansion barriers by giving card issuers (banks) significant financial incentives to favour
payment systems that offer interchange income. Potential new payment options would
likely need to compete on an interchange-like system (bidding up prices and distorting
price signals) in addition to providing improved functionality, if they are to be attractive
to consumers and banks.
Issue 5: Impact on small business
22. In addition to the inefficiency that the scheme interchange model is driving, there
appears to be systemically higher costs placed on smaller merchants to pay for the
processing of retail transactions. The interchange charged for small merchants can in
some cases be two and a half times the interchange rates for the largest, ‘strategic’
merchants. While there is likely to be some cost differential underlying the gap between
fees charged to large and small merchants, a closer look at the marginal costs involved
in processing transactions suggests that differences in underlying system costs are
unlikely to be a dominant driver of the growing differential in merchant service fees
between small and large merchants. If the spread were to increase further, we are
concerned that the disadvantage faced by smaller merchants could ultimately harm
retail competition.
Next steps
23. The Ministry of Business, Innovation and Employment considers that the nature and the
scale of the issues identified in the credit market, and the potential for these issues to
develop in the debit market, warrant additional work to address these issues. Similar
issues have been identified around the world, and it is only in countries where some sort
of regulatory intervention has occurred that these impacts have been addressed.
24. The Government is now testing the Ministry’s analysis and proposed next steps before
any decision is made about whether to progress this work further. Questions have been
posed throughout this paper for your consideration.
25. If the Government does choose to progress this work further, the complexity of the
retail payment system and the potential pace of change means that it will be important
for the following to be taken into account when developing a way forward:
the New Zealand context;
the effectiveness and net benefits of each option;
any consequential impacts on consumers and merchants, investment in innovation,
and development of the broader retail payments sector; and
the timeliness of any intervention.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
10
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
26. Should further work be undertaken, it would involve close engagement with
stakeholders, in order to ensure that any proposals make the best use of industry
expertise and take into account any stakeholder concerns.
27. The Ministry considers that further investigation would be worthwhile on the following:
The costs and benefits of applying interchange regulation to the credit market (and
the under which it would be applied in the debit market).
Whether there are economic, institutional and technical barriers to entry and
expansion for new payment methods in the debit market, and options for addressing
any such barriers.
Examination of other options, including: whether the governance of payment
systems can be improved; whether lighter-touch regulation, such as an industry code
of conduct, would have merit; whether EFTPOS could be made a sustainable
alternative to scheme debit products; and whether the retail payment system, or a
part of the system, should be treated like a utility.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
11
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
1. Introduction
28. In February 2016, the Minister of Finance, the Hon Bill English; and the Minister of
Commerce and Consumer Affairs, the Hon Paul Goldsmith, asked officials to undertake a
study into retail payment systems in New Zealand. The objective of the study was to test
whether the system in its current state, and as it is likely to develop in the future is
delivering good outcomes for consumers and merchants and the New Zealand economy
as a whole.
29. The decision to undertake a study into retail payments was triggered by a number of
factors, including:
merchant concerns about increasing fees for the processing of electronic
transactions;
industry developments, including the adoption of new technologies; and
ongoing reforms to the oversight and regulation of retail payment systems in
overseas jurisdictions.
30. Officials from the Ministry of Business, Innovation and Employment (MBIE) provided the
Government with a report in July 2016. It was developed in consultation with around 30
industry participants, including Retail New Zealand; small and large retailers; all major
banks, credit card schemes and ‘switches’; Consumer New Zealand; market challengers;
and independent experts. Some stakeholders provided us with non-public data to
support us to draw conclusions. While we have included as much information as
possible in this document, we have not published commercially sensitive information.
31. The report was independently reviewed by Dominic White of Pebble Payments and Mike
Laing of LWT Advisers. Both are payment systems specialists based in Australia.
32. The Government is now seeking feedback from stakeholders and the wider public on the
issues and proposed next steps outlined in this report. Questions have been posed
throughout this paper for your consideration.
Structure of this Issues Paper 1.1
33. The remainder of the Introduction sets the scene for the analysis that follows, by
defining the scope of the issues addressed in this Issues Paper, proposing public policy
objectives for retail payment systems, and outlining how retail payment systems are
currently regulated in New Zealand.
34. Section 2 outlines how retail payment systems work the main participants in the
system, the mechanics of how payments are processed, and trends in how different
retail payment options are being used.
35. Section 3 looks at the business models underpinning retail payment options, how costs
and charges flow through the system, and the incentives that result. This section also
considers the relative resource cost of putting payments through the various payment
channels.
36. Section 4 presents the issues we have identified with retail payment systems, as they
currently operate. This section looks at whether the market set up is achieving the sorts
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
12
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
of economic outcomes that are desirable, and whether this is likely to be the case as the
market evolves.
37. The final section outlines our preliminary thinking about next steps to address these
issues.
What are retail payment systems? 1.2
38. A payment system can be defined as the arrangements that allow consumers,
businesses and other organisations to transfer funds usually held in an account at one
financial institution to another. It includes the payment instruments cash, cheques and
electronic funds transfers which consumers use to make payments and the usually
unseen arrangements that ensure that funds move from accounts at one financial
institution to another.
1
39. There are various layers to a payment system:
the underlying network or “rails”, each with its own technical and operational
standardssuch as the Visa or MasterCard card networks, the Electronic Funds
Transfer at Point of Sale (EFTPOS) system, ‘direct entry’ into a bank account, or cash;
the product or method of payment that sits on these rails such as automatic
payments, direct debits, bank transfers, credit cards, online banking and mobile apps,
scheme debit cards, and proprietary EFTPOS cards; and
the initiator of the transaction i.e. consumer, business, or government.
40. This study considers retail payment systems, which we take to mean a system that is
used to clear (the transmission of information through the system to authenticate
identities and the availability of funds) and settle (the actual transfer of funds between
accounts) financial transactions between consumers and merchants
2
in return for goods
and services. Retail payment systems are distinguished from large-value payment
systems, which largely involve transactions made between financial institutions.
41. This study focuses particularly, but not exclusively, on card networks (Visa and
MasterCard) and the EFTPOS system, although other underlying networks and products
including potential emerging disruptors are considered throughout this report as
comparisons. While our focus is primarily on transactions made by consumers, many of
the issues discussed will nevertheless apply to business-to-business transactions.
42. Retail payment systems involve network effects, in that the value of the payment
system as a whole rises as more people use it. In particular, retail payment systems are a
form of two-sided market. Essentially, this means that for a given system to be
successful, it must attract both consumers and merchants to use its system. No
consumer will use a payment method if it is not accepted by a merchant, and no
merchant will accept a payment method that is not used by any consumer.
Objectives 1.3
43. This study is focussed on the economic outcomes delivered by retail payment systems in
New Zealand. This is complementary to the objectives held by other regulatory bodies in
New Zealand. For example, it is vital that payment systems are safe, secure and subject
1
Reserve Bank of Australia. (n.d.). Payments System. Retrieved from http://www.rba.gov.au/payments-
and-infrastructure/payments-system.html.
2
We use this term in a relatively wide sense in this Issues Paper to include payments made by
consumers to retailers, wholesalers, utilities companies, and central and local government.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
13
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
to prudential supervision. However, we do not focus on these objectives here, as the
Reserve Bank largely holds responsibility for these outcomes in its prudential role.
44. In considering whether good economic outcomes are being delivered, we have used the
following objectives to assess New Zealand’s retail payment systems:
Objective One: There is innovation and development of payment options that are
valued by consumers and businesses.
Objective Two: Resources are allocated efficiently at a system level. In the context of
retail payments, this means that the mix of transaction methods used represents the
underlying preferences of consumers and merchants, taking into account the
marginal benefits and costs of certain forms of payment to the system as a whole.
Objective Three: The cost associated with payment systems is distributed fairly
across consumers and merchants at an individual level.
45. These objectives of innovation, efficiency, and fair distribution of cost are tied to the
Government’s priority of building a more productive and competitive economy.
1 Are these objectives for retail payment systems appropriate?
46. We have not explicitly considered the competitiveness of the market. Competition can
take place within a payment system (such as between Visa and MasterCard), and
between payment systems (such as between credit cards and proprietary EFTPOS). In
terms of the former, as will be discussed throughout the Issues Paper, the two-sided
nature of retail payment systems means that it is possible for there to be competition
within a payment system, but for this to result in inefficient overall outcomes. In terms
of the latter, we see the outcomes (as captured by Objectives One to Three) as more
important than the input (i.e. the number of competing payment networks).
47. The ability to extract excessive profits is usually checked by competitive processes. We
have not examined profit levels, and whether these are ‘reasonable’, at any level of the
market. Such an exercise would be resource-intensive and difficult to undertake based
on publicly-available data. The analysis in this Issues Paper instead centres on the
economic incentives faced by market participants.
Regulation of retail payments in New Zealand 1.4
48. Retail payment systems are subject to relatively light-handed regulation in New Zealand.
Nevertheless, the following government and non-government regulatory bodies have
some form of oversight of their operation.
1.4.1 Prudential and system stability: Reserve Bank of New Zealand
49. Under the Reserve Bank Act 1989, the Reserve Bank has a mandate to promote the
maintenance of a sound and efficient financial system. In practice, the Reserve Bank has
not tended to treat efficiency as a standalone objective, but rather something that
should be pursued in conjunction with its soundness objective. Partly this is because a
focus on soundness is inherent in prudential regulation, and partly it is because
soundness and efficiency are mutually supporting concepts over the longer term.
50. In light of the fact that the Reserve Bank does not treat efficiency as a standalone
objective, it has minimised its role in respect of efficiency issues to a focus on access to,
and governance of, payment systems, minimising regulatory barriers to entry and
compliance costs, and effective market disclosure on soundness issues. As a result, the
performance and efficiency (allocative, dynamic, and productive) of retail payment
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
14
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
systems are not the primary focus of the Reserve Bank. This is in contrast to its
counterparts in countries such as Australia, which has a more direct ‘efficiency’ element
in their mandate. Since 2012, the Reserve Bank has been undertaking a review of its
oversight of financial market infrastructures (FMIs). That work is not designed to alter
the Reserve Bank’s approach to the retail payment systems we consider here.
1.4.2 Rules and standards for interoperability: Payments New Zealand
51. Payments New Zealand is the operator of a number of payment systems in New Zealand
(including the Consumer Electronic Clearing System, which includes proprietary EFTPOS).
It aims to promote simple, innovative, and secure payment systems in New Zealand.
Payments New Zealand was established in 2010 by eight banks (the shareholders) with a
mandate to open access to and preserve the integrity of New Zealand’s payment
systems. Prior to Payments New Zealand’s establishment, many of its functions were
undertaken by the New Zealand Bankers’ Association.
52. Payments New Zealand’s participants are banks that have joined one or more of its
clearing systems. Its members are payment system organisations (such as card schemes,
merchants, smaller non-shareholding banks, and payments infrastructure owners) that
want to be actively involved in the ongoing development and strategic direction of
payment systems. Its Board has 11 Directors made up of an Independent Chair, two
further Independent Directors and a Director appointed by each shareholder.
53. Payments New Zealand’s role is to:
Manage the rules and standards of its payment systems.
Encourage and facilitate new participants in its payment systems.
Facilitate interoperability of payments between its Participants.
Promote interoperable, innovative, safe, open and efficient payment systems.
54. In respect of the Consumer Electronic Clearing System, Payments New Zealand sets
standards relating to:
What an EFTPOS card must have and do, such as the requirement for a PIN.
What a merchant must do, such as make available a receipt.
The minimum requirements of the terminals that cardholders use to initiate their
transactions.
What, how, and when information gets exchanged through a switch.
55. Payments New Zealand has no (self-defined) role in determining the allocation of costs
or incentives within the retail payments system, or the business models that schemes
operate under.
1.4.3 Competition issues: Commerce Commission
56. The Commerce Commission (the Commission) has no prescribed role in relation to retail
payment systems, other than through its general role in enforcing the Commerce Act
1986, with the aim of promoting competition in markets for the long-term benefit of
New Zealand consumers.
57. In 2009, the Commission reached a settlement with the card schemes and major banks,
in which the parties made a number of undertakings to address what the Commission
considered was anti-competitive conduct in the operation of retail payment systems.
Annex 2 summarises the detail of the settlement.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
15
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
58. The settlement with banks and schemes expired in 2013. However, the settlement
continues to have residual impact. This is because if any of the parties re-commence any
of the practices that the Commission deemed to be anti-competitive, they may be re-
challenged for potentially breaching the Commerce Act. The exception may be the level
of interchange fees, which is not necessarily a breach of the Commerce Act in itself.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
16
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
2. Payment systems in New Zealand
Introduction 2.1
59. Electronic payment systems are a key piece of infrastructure for commerce. While
alternative payment options (such as cash and cheques) remain, they are increasingly on
the fringe and compete poorly with their electronic competitors in a number of
dimensions. For example, electronic payments:
Often provide greater convenience for consumers (such no need to visit a bank or an
ATM to withdraw cash, greater payment speed, and the ability to track and record
transactions).
Allow consumers to purchase online with ease.
Avoid the cost to merchants associated with processing cash and cheques (although
as discussed later, electronic payments are by no means costless).
May reduce the risk of bad debts, and cash and cheque-related fraud and theft.
In the case of credit cards, allow consumers to smooth consumption over time (this
also means that merchants do not need to operate their own credit schemes).
Generate greater certainty of tax revenue for governments.
Box 1: The value of credit cards for merchants
Many of the stakeholders we spoke to emphasised the value that electronic payments,
particularly credit cards, provide to merchants. These included the ability to accept
international transactions, the avoided cost of cash acceptance, payment guarantees against
fraud and credit losses, prompt payment benefits, and increased sales from existing and
new customers.
As noted above, electronic payments, including credit cards, unquestionably provide a
number of benefits to both merchants and consumers. However, we consider that the levels
of some of these benefits are contestable. For example:
Some parties noted that the value of average credit card transactions is higher than the
value of cash or debit transactions, and viewed this as evidence that credit cards
encourage higher levels of spending. An alternative interpretation is that any increase in
spending in the current period is countered by a reduction in spending in future periods,
and that higher credit card transaction values relative to other methods is correlation,
rather than causation. That is, higher-income individuals usually have larger than
average transaction sizes, and often use credit cards, but their transaction size would be
unlikely to change if they used a different payment method.
Some stakeholders also noted that the cost of payment card fraud sometimes rests with
merchants, i.e. it is not always covered by scheme or bank payment guarantees.
Similarly, while cash is unquestionably costly to process for merchants, we consider that
many of these costs are fixed, and unlikely to disappear without a complete withdrawal
of cash from circulation.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
17
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
60. New Zealand is highly regarded internationally for having one of the most developed,
dynamic, safe and secure payment systems in the world.
3
In line with this, uptake of
electronic payments in New Zealand is high: 93.8 per cent of adults have and use an
EFTPOS/debit card; New Zealand has the highest number of electronic payments made
per capita; and New Zealand has the lowest proportion of cash to GDP in circulation.
4
Furthermore, a 2014 survey ranked New Zealand as the number one global pioneering
payments market. This was based on consumer preferences for using electronic
payment options for low-value payments, willingness to use contactless forms of
electronic payments, and receptivity to changes in electronic payments.
5
61. As will be discussed later, much of this is attributable to the business model that
underpinned the rollout of proprietary EFTPOS, which encouraged almost universal
acceptance of card payments by merchants.
62. The remainder of this section outlines at a high level the main participants involved in
retail payment systems in New Zealand, the main types of card payment, and how these
payments are processed. It also briefly outlines emerging payment methods, such as
Apple Pay.
Parties in the system 2.2
63. There are a number of parties involved in any card-based transaction. The parties
involved and the interactions between them will differ depending on the type of card
being used. Nevertheless, the key parties and their key roles include:
Cardholder/customer/consumer: Buys goods and services from merchants in
exchange for payment.
Merchant: A party that provides goods or services in return for payment. Includes
retailers, wholesalers, utilities companies, and central and local government.
Issuer: An organisation, typically a bank, which issues cards and provides debit
and/or credit services to consumers.
Acquirer: An organisation, typically a bank, which provides access to the payment
system on behalf of merchants for the clearing and settlement of funds in a
transaction. An acquirer may or may not also be the bank that provides other
services to a merchant, such as lending and deposits.
Scheme: Includes Visa, MasterCard, American Express and Diners. Schemes develop
technology and base product features, and set the commercial model and card
system rules. They may issue cards and attract merchants through banks (open
system Visa and MasterCard) or directly (closed system American Express, Diners
Club, etc.). Only relevant for non-proprietary-EFTPOS transactions.
Switch: Infrastructure that sends the transaction information to the correct card
issuer or acquirer (depending on the type of transaction) so the funds can be taken
from the consumer's account and delivered to the merchant. Switching functions can
be performed by various parties, including stand-alone switches (most notably
3
Payments New Zealand. (2016). Benchmarking New Zealand’s payment systems. Unpublished.
4
Payments New Zealand. (2015). Are our payment systems as good as we think they are? Retrieved
from http://www.paymentsnz.co.nz/articles/are-our-payment-systems-as-good-as-we-think-they-are
.
5
RFIntelligence. (2014). Identifying global leaders in the race to transform national payment markets.
Retrieved from
http://www.rfintelligence.com/downloads/RFi_Global%20Report%20May%202014%20-
%20FINAL%20VERSION.pdf
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
18
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
Paymark), schemes, and vertically-integrated terminal providers and customer
gateways (such as Verifone and Payment Express). The term here is distinguished
from an inter-bank switch that processes high-value payments, which is not further
discussed in this Issues Paper.
Customer interface: Either the terminal hardware and software (for card-present
transactions) or digital customer gateway (for card-not-present transactions) through
which the customer makes a payment to a merchant.
Types of payment card and the types of transactions 2.3
64. This subsection outlines the types of debit and credit cards that are available, the types
of transactions that they can be used for, and how they are processed (or “switched”) in
the system. These relationships are summarised in Table 1. The method of switching is
important because it is tied to the business model applied to the transaction by banks
and schemes. This is discussed further in Sections 3 and 4.
Table 1: Cards, transactions and switches
Type of card Type of transaction Method of switch/network
Proprietary EFTPOS Swiped
Switch to issuer
(domestic rails’)
Scheme debit
Inserted/swiped
Contactless/card-not-present
Switch to acquirer
(scheme rails’)
Open or closed credit
Swiped/inserted/contactless/card-
not-present
2.3.1 Proprietary EFTPOS cards
65. Proprietary EFTPOS is the traditional form of debit payment card used in New Zealand.
According to data provided to us by one of New Zealand’s switches, it has a current
market share of roughly 46 per cent of transactions (by volume). It was introduced in
New Zealand in 1984 as a series of separately run switches and trials, and was
progressively rolled out and consolidated through the 1980s.
6
The system was
developed by banks as a means of reducing the high cost associated with processing
cash and cheque payments, largely without government involvement. Cards are issued
by a consumer’s bank, and while Payments New Zealand maintains an interoperability
standard for EFTPOS, there is no ‘owner’ of EFTPOS as a product.
66. For reasons explored later in this Issues Paperand in contrast to other countries such
as Australia and Canada EFTPOS as a technology in New Zealand remains
fundamentally unchanged from when it was introduced in the 1980s. Payment
information is transmitted via a magnetic strip on an EFTPOS card, which is less secure
than other methods of electronic transmission of information. In addition, at present,
EFTPOS cards can only be used to pay for face-to-face transactions (card-present
6
Wilkinson, M. (2011). Development of Retail Payment Systems since 1949. Master’s Thesis. Retrieved
from http://hdl.handle.net/10063/1747
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
19
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
transactions), rather than online or over-the-phone sales (card-not-present
transactions). EFTPOS cards are also unable to be used for transactions made overseas.
67. Proprietary EFTPOS transactions are processed via a ‘switch to issuer’ model (domestic
rails – see Section 2.4).
2.3.2 Standard scheme debit cards
68. The first standard scheme debit card (named as such to distinguish it from contactless
scheme debit see below) was introduced to New Zealand in 2006. The cards are issued
by a consumer’s bank using the technology and standards set by a card scheme at
present, either Visa or MasterCard. In addition to a magnetic strip, scheme debit cards
also contain a chip that is inserted into a terminal, which provides greater security.
When inserted or swiped, scheme debit cards are currently processed under a ‘switch to
issuer’ model (discussed below) in the same way as proprietary EFTPOS, and funds are
accessed from the same bank account.
69. In addition to ‘card-present’ transactions, scheme debit cards can be also be used to pay
any merchant that accepts payments via the relevant scheme online, over the phone, or
overseas. In these instances, debit cards are ‘switched to acquirer’ (see below) process.
Scheme debit cards, when inserted or swiped, represent approximately 20 per cent of
transactions.
2.3.3 Contactless scheme debit
70. Since 2011, contactless debit cards (known as Visa PayWave and MasterCard PayPass)
have progressively entered circulation in New Zealand. In addition to inserting or
swiping a card, consumers have the option of ‘tapping’ their card against a terminal. This
allows payment for transactions below a threshold (currently $80, as set by Visa and
MasterCard) to be made contactlessly without the use of a PIN or signature.
71. When contactless functionality is used, scheme debit cards operate under a ‘switch to
acquirer’ model, even if the transaction exceeds the $80 limit and a PIN is required.
Swiping or inserting a contactless scheme debit card will see the transaction switched to
the issuer instead, in the same way that proprietary EFTPOS and standard scheme debit
transactions are processed. Contactless scheme debit is used for approximately 10 per
cent of transactions (but this share is rapidly growing).
2.3.4 Open credit card schemes
72. The first credit cards were introduced to New Zealand in the late 1970s. Open credit
card systems (often known as four-party systems) are the dominant form of credit card
system in New Zealand, and involve a card scheme (predominantly Visa and MasterCard)
working through issuers and acquirers (mainly banks) to attract consumers and
merchants to use and accept their product, respectively.
73. Open credit card schemes provide functionality similar to that of scheme debit cards,
with the obvious difference that they involve credit- rather than debit-based
transactions. It is the banks (as issuers), rather than card schemes, that provide
consumers with credit, and who guarantee the payment to merchants through their
acquirers. Open credit card systems are processed under a ‘switch to acquirer’ model
(see below).
74. Open credit cards have benefited from considerable investment and innovation on the
part of the schemes and banks. As a result of this, and significant marketing efforts
(discussed later), schemes have built an extensive international network of usage and
acceptance.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
20
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
75. Open credit cards often have contactless functionality but regardless of whether a credit
card is inserted, swiped or used contactlessly, the transaction is switched to the
acquirer. Open and closed (see below) credit cards are collectively used for
approximately 24 per cent of transactions.
2.3.5 Closed credit card schemes
76. The last major form of payment card is a closed credit card scheme (often known as a
three-party system). Under such a system, the scheme such as American Express or
Diners Clubis also the issuer and acquirer of payment cards. That means that the
scheme directly works to attract consumers to use, and merchants to accept, their
payment cards. In addition, it is the scheme that is the provider of credit to a consumer.
77. Closed credit card schemes are processed under a ‘switch to acquirer’ model. We
understand that the market share of closed credit card schemes in New Zealand is
relatively low, at around 2 per cent of all card-based transactions.
Methods of switching 2.4
78. There are two main ways in which a card-based transaction can be processed, or
‘switched’: switch-to-issuer and switch-to-acquirer.
2.4.1 Switch to issuer (domestic rails)
79. When a proprietary EFTPOS card is used, or a scheme debit card is inserted or swiped,
the transaction is processed via a ‘switch to issuer’ model. Under this process:
A switch sends the transaction details from the customer interface to the issuing
bank for authorisation.
The issuing bank authorises or declines the transaction and returns the message to
the customer interface.
The money is immediately debited (cleared) from the customer’s account at the time
it is authorised.
Funds are settled between the cardholder’s and merchant’s financial institutions via
the inter-bank settlement process and deposited in the merchant’s account in a
lump-sum each day after inter-bank settlement.
2.4.2 Switch to acquirer (scheme rails)
80. A payment is processed using a ‘switch to acquirer’ model for all credit card
transactions, and for contactless, card-not-present, and international scheme debit
transactions. When this occurs:
A transaction is switched from a customer interface to an acquirer (how it gets there
depends on the channel in which the transaction originates).
The acquirer switches the transaction details to the card scheme.
The scheme sends the authorisation request to the issuing bank.
The issuing bank confirms whether the cardholder has sufficient available credit to
cover the purchase, and returns a response through the card scheme network, either
granting or denying authorisation.
The acquirer receives the response and returns the message to the customer
interface.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
21
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
The acquiring bank reconciles and transmits authorisations via the appropriate
scheme. Funds are deposited in a merchant’s account in a lump-sum after inter-bank
settlement, and debited from a customer’s balance in accordance with the relevant
scheme’s rules.
Schemes settle funds with acquirers within 72 hours of the transaction occurring.
2.4.3 Variations
81. There are a number of variations to these two methods. These include cases where the
customer interface also acts as the switch, where the transaction bypasses a stand-alone
switch to be switched purely by a scheme, and when a transaction is processed by a self-
acquirer. These variations are not important for the purposes of this Issues Paper. As will
be discussed in Sections 3 and 4, what matters is whether a transaction passes through a
scheme as all switch-to-acquirer transactions inherently dosince this determines the
business model under which the transaction takes place.
Trends in usage of payment options 2.5
82. In the year to March 2016, New Zealanders made more than 1.5 billion electronic card
transactions, representing more than $76 billion in expenditure. Transactions made
using electronic cards were responsible for 68.5 per cent of retail trade revenue in core
industries (excluding vehicle and fuel sales), an increase from 58.8 per cent in 2004 (see
Figure 1).
7
This means that the total share of other forms of payment (including cash,
cheques, bank transfers, and direct debits) is falling. In addition, the average value of
each electronic transaction is falling over time, reflecting the displacement of cash
(which is often used for low-value transactions).
Figure 1: Value of electronic card transactions as a percentage of total core retail
trade sales (Statistics New Zealand data)
83. Figure 2 shows that the split between credit and debit has remained relatively constant
since 2002.
8
7
Statistics New Zealand. (2016). Electronic Card Transactions. Retrieved from
http://www.stats.govt.nz/browse_for_stats/businesses/business_characteristics/electronic-card-
transactions-info-releases.aspx.
8
The slight upward trend in credit card usage in the last two years is misleading and represents the
miscategorisation of contactless debit transactions as credit transactions in the data provided to
Statistics New Zealand by New Zealand switches.
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016
%
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
22
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
Figure 2: Credit and debit card transactions as a percentage of electronic card
transactions (Statistics New Zealand data)
84. Even though the split between debit and credit spend has remained relatively constant,
there has been a notable shift in the types of transaction taking place over the last two
years, according to figures provided to us by one of New Zealand’s domestic switches.
Figure 3 (below) shows a significant decline in the value of transactions made with
proprietary EFTPOS cards, from around 44 per cent of card transactions in January 2014,
to 36 per cent in April 2016. There has also been a corresponding increase in the value
of contactless debit transactions, from 1 to 7 per cent of total transaction value. This has
taken the share of transactions that are processed via scheme rails from 40 to 49 per
cent of the transactions processed by this switch.
Figure 3: Value of electronic card transactions by card type (New Zealand switch
data)
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
2002Q4
2003Q2
2003Q4
2004Q2
2004Q4
2005Q2
2005Q4
2006Q2
2006Q4
2007Q2
2007Q4
2008Q2
2008Q4
2009Q2
2009Q4
2010Q2
2010Q4
2011Q2
2011Q4
2012Q2
2012Q4
2013Q2
2013Q4
2014Q2
2014Q4
2015Q2
2015Q4
Credit card usage as a proportion of total electronic card transactions value
Debit card usage as a proportion of total electronic card transactions value
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
90%
100%
Credit Card Credit Card (Contactless) Scheme Debit (Contactless)
Scheme Debit (Swipe/Insert) Proprietary EFTPOS
Switch to
acquirer
(scheme
rails)
Switch to
issuer
(domestic
rails)
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
23
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
85. Figure 4 provides the same transaction data, but by the number of transactions, rather
than their value. Switch-to-acquirer transactions form a lower proportion of this graph
than Figure 3, because the average value of credit card transactions is higher than for
other cards.
Figure 4: Number of electronic card transactions by card type (New Zealand switch
data)
Emerging payment methods 2.6
86. In addition to card-based payments, there are a number of other payment methods that
have been launched over the past few years, or are soon to be released. These can be
broken down into:
Those that utilise existing scheme rails, which mean that a scheme debit or credit
card is required for payment.
Those that do not rely on scheme rails. Many of these involve ‘direct entry’ to a
consumer’s bank account, otherwise known as a bank-to-bank transfer. While direct
entry methods are not new, the integration of them into a merchant’s point-of-sale
(POS) system is.
87. Payment methods can also be distinguished by whether they are used for card-present
or card-not-present (predominantly online) transactions, although over time this
distinction may blur.
88. Table 2 outlines many of these emerging methods.
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
90%
100%
Credit Card Credit Card (Contactless) Scheme Debit (Contactless)
Scheme Debit (Swipe/Insert) Proprietary EFTPOS
Switch to
acquirer
(scheme
rails)
Switch to
issuer
(domestic
rails)
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
24
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
Table 2: Types of emerging payment method
Name Rails Type of transaction Description
Apple Pay Scheme Card-present and
card-not-present
Contactless payment option that utilises
Apple devices instead of a card. Recently
launched in New Zealand for ANZ
customers. Utilises near-field
communication technology to enable
payment at any terminal where
contactless payments are accepted. In
addition, Apple Pay facilitates faster
payments within apps on Apple devices.
Android Pay Scheme Card-present and
card-not-present
Similar to Apple Pay, but for Android
devices. Not yet available in New
Zealand. Android Pay also facilitates
faster purchases within Android apps.
goMoney
wallet
Scheme Card-present Launched by ANZ in 2015. Similar to the
above, but operates from within the
existing ANZ mobile app on compatible
Android phones. GoMoney also supports
payments between ANZ accounts using a
cell phone number, so is also a direct
entry payment method in this respect.
Direct entry Card-not-present
ASB Virtual Scheme Card-present Similar to GoMoney wallet. ASB’s mobile
app also supports direct entry payment
through the use of cell phone numbers
or email addresses.
Direct entry Card-not-present
PayTag Scheme Card-present A sticker that a consumer attaches to
their phone (or anything else). This
utilises the same technology as that
contained in a contactless card. Offered
by ASB for Visa products, and Westpac
for MasterCard products.
PayPal Scheme or
direct entry
Card-not-present Allows consumers to pay for goods and
services online by entering their email
address and password. While generally
linked to a scheme card, a PayPal
account can also be funded through
direct entry methods. PayPal acts an
alternate acquirer for merchants who
may not have a relationship with an
acquiring bank.
MasterPass Scheme Card-not-present A digital wallet developed by MasterCard
that stores a consumer’s payment and
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
25
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
shipping information in one location. This
allows consumers to make faster online
payments with merchants that have
integrated MasterPass into their
payment gateway. Despite being
developed by MasterCard, it can also be
used with Visa, American Express and
Diners Club cards.
Visa
Checkout
Scheme Card-not-present Similar to MasterPass.
POLi Direct entry Card-not-present Introduced in New Zealand in 2009.
When paying via POLi at an online
checkout, a consumer selects their bank
and enters their internet banking details,
POLi populates the transaction details,
and the consumer confirms payment.
While a number of online merchants,
including Air New Zealand and the
Warehouse accept POLi, banks have
expressed concern that payment
methods like POLi expose consumers to
increased risk and could be in breach of
banks’ terms and conditions.
Account2
Account
Direct entry Card-not-present Operated by Payment Express. Similar to
POLi.
PayHere Direct entry Card-not-present Launched by ASB in 2013. Under this
system, any ASB customer can pay a
participating merchant by entering their
cell phone number in the merchant’s
payment gateway, and confirming the
payment via their ASB mobile app. No
bank account details are exchanged, and
transactions are processed instantly.
Because PayHere sits within a merchant
gateway, businesses do not need to have
a banking relationship with ASB to accept
PayHere payments. Merchant
acceptance of PayHere appears to be
relatively low.
89. In addition, we understand that Paymark is in the process of finalising its own online
EFTPOS solution, which works similarly to PayHere.
90. Many of the above scheme-based methods utilise what is known as ‘tokenisation’. This
supports greater security rather than providing the scheme card number to the
terminal, the terminal receives a device-specific ‘token’ and a one-use-only security
code. The token is translated into a credit card number only when it reaches the
scheme, meaning that only the scheme and the issuer have information about both the
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
26
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
person and the transaction. Tokenisation also avoids the technical limitations that can
be associated with the unique card number on a physical card.
91. Crucially, other than switch-to-issuer transactions, there are not currently any
mainstream electronic payment methods in New Zealand that facilitate direct entry for
store-based (i.e. card-present) transactions. However, we are aware of industry
participants that are exploring options around the development of payment methods
that bypass scheme infrastructure through the use of:
Blockchaina digital ledger that records transactions which resides not on a single
server, but across a distributed network of computers. Ripple is a company that
utilises a distributed ledger process to enable participants to directly transact with
each other in real time, without the need for a central counterparty. The widespread
applicability of this technology to retail payments is seemingly some time away, but
should not be discounted.
Application programme interfaces (APIs) sets of routines, protocols, and tools for
building software applications. These have the potential to make it easier for industry
to offer bank-to-bank payment solutions that build off a common set of
infrastructure. For example, if banks allowed APIs to access their internet banking
platforms, it would allow non-banks to develop payment products over the top of the
issuer-customer banking relationship. The European Union’s revised Directive on
Payment Services (PSD2) is an example of an attempt by government to stimulate
competition in payments by allowing authorised third parties to use a consumer’s
bank details to make payments from their account.
2
Are there any other emerging payment methods that we have missed? If so, what is their
likely impact on the market?
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
27
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
3. Market business models and
resource costs
93. The previous section described, at a basic level, how retail payments are processed
between parties. This section builds on that by describing the flows of fees and
inducements under the various business models operating in New Zealand.
94. First, we introduce the business model underpinning switch-to-issuer transactions,
which is relatively straightforward. We then move onto describing the interchange
business model that underpins switch-to-acquirer transactions. This is a complex set of
relationships that drives the uptake of each product as well as the market share of
various products. In particular, we focus on the following four relationships:
Card issuers (generally banks) and consumers.
Issuers and acquirers (and the flow of interchange fees).
Acquirers (generally banks) and merchants (and the payment of merchant service
fees, MSFs).
Consumers and merchants (and the use of surcharging and steering).
Switch-to issuer transactions 3.1
3.1.1 Overview
95. Very little flows in the way of fees and charges when it comes to transactions that are
switched to the issuer (run on domestic rails), including all payments made on
proprietary EFTPOS cards and inserted and swiped transactions made on scheme debit
cards.
96. Charges to cardholders for switch-to-issuer transactions are rare, and the marginal cost
of these transactions to merchants is zero. While merchants do face fixed costs for
terminal hire and the per-terminal cost of being connected to a switch, these costs are
carried by all merchants that take electronic card payments, regardless of which
payment types they accept. We therefore refer to switch-to-issuer transactions as being
“free” to merchants for the remainder of this Issues Paper.
97. As a result, the cost to banks of processing these transactions is met from other bank
income sources. A key (but still relatively small) cost of processing switch-to-issuer
transactions is the cost of switching itself, a function provided by Paymark and Verifone
for these transactions. The issuing bank pays these switching costs.
98. Figure 5 below shows the flows of fees and inducements that underlie the relationship
between different parties for switch-to-issuer transactions. Some of these flows are only
applicable in certain situations. The majority of the lines in the diagram are dashed,
which represents the fact that the flows of funds are not substantial in respect of switch-
to-issuer transactions.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
28
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
Figure 5: Fees and inducements in switch-to-issuer transactions
3.1.2 Customer-issuer relationships
99. It is important to see issuing banks’ competition for debit payment products as part of
their broader competition for personal banking consumers. This is because debit cards
are tied to a customer’s current account and a customer usually has their current
account with the bank that provides the remainder of their more significant banking
services (for example, their mortgage). This contrasts with credit cards, where it is more
common for someone to take out a credit card with a different bank to the one that
provides their other personal banking services.
100. There are flows of funds in both directions between customers and issuers related to
the maintenance of transactional bank accounts:
Account fees, transaction fees and card fees that are paid from the customer to the
issuer.
Interest, and occasionally rewards, that are paid to the customer by the issuer.
101. It is difficult to separate the flows relating to the operation of the account from flows
relating to the use of the payment functionality of a proprietary EFTPOS or scheme debit
card. Nevertheless, in general, banks do not charge consumers to use proprietary
EFTPOS or scheme debit cards, although some current accounts do attract a low
monthly fee that contributes to the overall cost of running the account. Per-transaction
fees were common when EFTPOS was introduced but over time they have been largely
competed away for most account types. Some banks also charge consumers a low
annual fee for a scheme debit card.
102. We have been advised that these charges do not fully offset the cost of providing these
debit payment options. Therefore, these costs are generally partially funded by banks
through other mechanisms, such as reduced interest payments to consumers on debit
balances (and interchange fees when the card is used contactlessly).
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
29
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
103. Table 3 presents four (relatively representative) account types tied to scheme debit
cards that were available in January 2016.
Table 3: Examples of scheme debit fees, interest and rewards as at January 2016
(public data)
BNZ YouMoney
FlexiDebit Visa
ASB Omni
Westpac Access
Airpoints Debit
MasterCard
TSB Personal Visa
Debit
Account fee
$5/month
$0
$3.50/month
$0
Transaction
fee
$0
$0.40/transaction
$0
$0
Card fee
$10.00 p.a.
$10.00 p.a.
$15.00 p.a.
$10.00 p.a.
Interest rate
(on savings)
0% p.a.
0% p.a.
0% p.a.
1.00% p.a. on
balances above $500;
1.50% p.a. on
balances above
$10,000.
Rewards
NA.
NA.
1 Airpoint per $250
spent.
NA.
104. There are generally no inducements to use proprietary EFTPOS or scheme debit cards.
This is likely to be less to do with a lack of competition in the debit card market, and
more because (with the exception of contactless debit transactions) there is no
interchange revenue to fund the inducements (see Section 3.2.3 for a discussion of
interchange). However, in 2015, Westpac introduced a modest rewards programme with
the launch of its Airpoints Debit MasterCard. So far, no other bank has followed suit in
launching a debit card rewards programme.
105. We are not aware of any major bank that does not continue to offer proprietary EFTPOS
cards to customers who request them. However, scheme debit cards have largely
become the default card offered by many issuers due to customer demand for the
greater functionality of scheme debit (such as online payment), and financial incentives
on issuers (see Section 4).
9
Banks have told us that the schemes now require all scheme
debit cards that are issued to contain contactless technology.
3.1.3 Issuer-acquirer relationships
106. A flow of funds between issuers and acquirers is known as interchange, and is discussed
further in Section 3.2.3 below. However, no interchange is charged on debit transactions
that are switched to issuer. This is a long-standing feature for proprietary EFTPOS
transactions and was continued for inserted and swiped scheme debit transactions
when scheme debit cards entered the market in 2006.
9
At least one major bank continues to have a high number of proprietary EFTPOS cards in circulation.
However, we know from Figures 3 and 4 (above) that usage of these cards is nevertheless declining
relatively quickly.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
30
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
107. Our understanding is that New Zealand is relatively unique in the schemes not charging
interchange on the majority of scheme debit transactions.
10
The explanation for this
situation appears to be largely that, because merchants do not pay a fee to accept
proprietary EFTPOS payments (see below), few merchants would have accepted scheme
debit cards upon their introduction were there an associated charge. In addition,
because (at introduction) no issuer offered rewards on scheme debit products, there
was no need to meet the cost associated with these inducements.
3.1.4 Acquirer-merchant relationships
108. Merchants face costs as part of their overall relationship with a bank. However, because
switch-to-issuer transactions operate outside of the interchange business model,
merchants do not face any per-transaction charge for these payments. This traces back
to the introduction of EFTPOS in the 1980s, in which banks keen to see a shift away
from cash and cheques and their associated cost placed charges for EFTPOS on
consumers, rather than merchants, in order to drive acceptance.
109. As noted above, over time these charges on cardholders have largely been competed
away, meaning banks receive no direct revenue source from the processing of EFTPOS
and standard scheme debit cards. At least one acquirer attempted to introduce a MSF
for proprietary EFTPOS in the 1990s, but quickly removed these in the face of heavy
attrition from merchant customers.
Switch-to-acquirer transactions 3.2
3.2.1 Overview
110. Scheme-based transactions involve a significantly more complex series of fees and
inducements that flow between more parties in the system. In this Issues Paper, we call
the nexus of relationships underpinning scheme-based transactions the “interchange
business model”. This business model applies to:
All open (Visa and MasterCard) credit cards.
Contactless scheme debit transactions.
Card-not-present scheme debit transactions (mainly online).
International scheme debit transactions.
111. Figure 6 below shows the main flows of fees and inducements in switch-to-acquirer
transactions. Once again, not all flows are applicable to all situations. Bold lines
represent flows that are ‘core’ to understanding the system, while dotted lines
represent secondary flows.
10
However, there are many markets worldwide in which EFTPOS-like systems have been developed
without the use of interchange.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
31
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
Figure 6: Fees and inducements in switch-to-acquirer transactions
3.2.2 Customer-issuer relationships
112. Generally speaking, there are three variables on which credit card issuers compete for
credit card customers: card annual fees, interest rates on credit, and reward
programmes. There are therefore three main types of credit card offered in the market
at present: low fee/low rewards/high interest rate; high fee/high rewards/high interest
rate; and low fee/no rewards/low interest rate. Table 4 provides examples of five
(relatively representative) credit cards available in January 2016.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
32
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
Table 4: Example of credit card fees, interest and rewards as at January 2016
ANZ Low
Rate
MasterCard
ASB Visa Gold
Rewards
Platinum
Kiwibank
Airpoints
Standard
MasterCard
American
Express Air
New
Zealand
Westpac Airpoints
World MasterCard
Card fee
$58 p.a.
$150 p.a.
$65 p.a.
$0 p.a.
$390 p.a.
Interest
rate (on
credit)
13.90% p.a.
20.95% p.a.
20.95% p.a.
19.95% p.a.
16.95% p.a.
Rewards
NA.
$1 True
Rewards per
$100 spent,
travel
insurance.
$1 Airpoint
dollar per
$120 spent.
1 Airpoint
per $100
spent.
1 Airpoint per $65 spent,
1 status point per $225,
travel insurance,
extended warrantee
insurance, airport lounge
access, valet parking.
113. It seems more likely that a consumer will switch bank on the basis of a credit card
offering than a debit card for one thing, a credit card customer does not need to hold
funds with an issuer, while a debit customer does. In line with this, competition between
issuers in relation to credit cards appears to be relatively intense. Issuers invest
significantly in marketing to attract customers to their product. This appears to be
happening through both churn of existing customers between issuers, and the drawing
of non-credit card users to credit. For example, Reserve Bank data
11
shows domestic
inflation-adjusted spending on credit cards has increased nearly six-fold since 1993 (see
Figure 7). In fact, in the year to February 2016, domestic spending on credit cards
increased by 13.6 per cent on the year before.
12
114. Having said this, as noted above, the share of credit card transactions as a proportion of
all electronic card transactions has remained relatively constant since 2002 (when
records began) indicating that there has been a similar growth in the level of
transactions carried out on debit cards over this period.
Figure 7: Monthly spend on New Zealand-issued credit cards, seasonally adjusted,
2016 dollars ($ millions, RBNZ data, MBIE calculations)
11
Reserve Bank of New Zealand. (2016). Credit card spending. Retrieved from
http://www.rbnz.govt.nz/statistics/c13
.
12
MWE Consulting. (2016). New Zealand Cards Report: February 2016.
$-
$500
$1,000
$1,500
$2,000
$2,500
$3,000
$3,500
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
33
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
115. Reserve Bank data
13
also shows that credit card usage may be increasing for reasons
other than consumers needing credit. Figure 8 shows that the revolve ratio on credit
cards that is, the ratio of interest-bearing advances to all advances is at its lowest
point since records began, with 36 per cent of balances attracting no interest. We
assume that interest-bearing advances are spending that is dependent on credit (since it
is not being paid off before it attracts interest) and that non-interest-bearing advances
are spending that is not dependent on credit (or, at the most, only on very short-term
credit, since it is paid off within a very short timeframe). Therefore, the decrease in the
revolve ratio suggests that consumers may be being induced to use credit more than
they otherwise would.
3 What explains the decline in the revolve ratio on credit cards?
116. Similarly, the ratio of credit card expenditure to outstanding balances is also increasing.
These trends align with bank assertions that while around half of credit card customers
use their cards primarily for the credit functionality, another 40 per cent are using them
primarily on the basis of the rewards they provide.
Figure 8: Revolve ratio on credit cards (RBNZ data, MBIE calculations)
117. Issuers have three main revenue streams from which the costs associated with credit
cards are funded: annual fees, interchange income (discussed later), and interest rates.
Ultimately, these all feed into the same ‘pool’ of funds for the bank, so they cannot be
considered completely separately. However, at least for one major bank, these revenue
streams are generally tied to different costs:
Annual fees to customers are generally used to cover costs related to the physical
cost of the card, customer service and administration, and statements. They are also
used to fund some benefits of holding or using the card, such as travel insurance,
concierge services and Visa Entertainment.
Interchange income is used to pay for rewards such as Air New Zealand Airpoints, or
issuer-specific cash-back or voucher-style rewards programmes, which are tied to the
value of spending on a card. Rewards are determined by the issuer, rather than the
13
Reserve Bank of New Zealand. (2016). C12: Credit card balances. Retrieved from
http://www.rbnz.govt.nz/statistics/c12
.
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
Jul 2000
Mar 2001
Nov 2001
Jul 2002
Mar 2003
Nov 2003
Jul 2004
Mar 2005
Nov 2005
Jul 2006
Mar 2007
Nov 2007
Jul 2008
Mar 2009
Nov 2009
Jul 2010
Mar 2011
Nov 2011
Jul 2012
Mar 2013
Nov 2013
Jul 2014
Mar 2015
Nov 2015
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
34
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
scheme. Interchange income may also cover scheme fees and the cost of fraud,
meaning that not all interchange income necessarily flows to cardholders.
Interest income from interest-bearing balances is used to pay for the cost of credit
(including the interest-free period) and bad debts, rather than the cost of payment
per se. For this reason, it is not the focus of this study. Nevertheless, Reserve Bank
data
14
shows that weighted average interest rates on credit card balances have
remained relatively stable over the past 15 years, at around 18 per cent on interest-
bearing balances, and 12 per cent across all balances (i.e. the average of the balance
attracting interest and the balance not attracting interest).
118. One bank provided us with information about the levels of rewards paid out, relative to
the annual fees collected on credit cards over the last three years. While the two are not
necessarily connected, the rewards paid out have substantially exceeded the annual
fees collected in all three years, with significant growth in rewards paid (but not annual
fees collected) out over the last two years.
119. One bank has told us that more than 70 per cent of credit card spending attracts
rewards (this will vary by issuer depending on their product range). Reward levels are
difficult to track using publicly available data due to frequent changes in the structure of
reward programmes. However, data provided to us by a major bank shows that the level
of reward per dollar spent was relatively flat between 2009 and 2014, before rising
significantly in 2015 and 2016. Much of this appears to be attributable to increased
competition between issuers to attract (and retain) the customers of BNZ, following the
end of its Airpoints arrangement with Air New Zealand.
120. The overall increase in rewards paid out therefore likely reflects two factors:
increased spending on rewards-based credit cards; and
an increase in the rewards offered per dollar spent.
Figure 9: Examples of the strong competition between banks for rewards
121. Much of both the increased spending on rewards-based credit cards and the increase in
the average level of rewards per dollar is likely attributable to the increase in the
14
Reserve Bank of New Zealand. (2016). C12: Credit card balances. Retrieved from
http://www.rbnz.govt.nz/statistics/c12
..
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
35
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
number of customers on ‘premium’ credit cards (those with high rewards, and
correspondingly higher interchange fees discussed later) in recent years. This has been
a consistent theme of our discussions with stakeholders, and is confirmed by data
provided to us by one bank, which shows that the number of premium cards issued by
that bank has quintupled (albeit from a relatively low base) since 2008.
122. Interest-free periods are another form of credit card inducement. These generally last
for up to either 44 or 55 days, depending on the period in a billing cycle in which a
payment is made. These periods serve to make credit card payments more attractive by
making the cost of short-term credit effectively zero equivalent to debit, and much
cheaper than other forms of credit such as overdrafts, which do not generally have
interest-free periods.
123. Closed credit cards schemes such as American Express generally operate similarly to
open schemes in respect of fees and rewards.
3.2.3 Issuer-acquirer relationships
The theory of interchange
124. The flow of funds between issuers and acquirers that takes place under switch-to-
acquirer transactions is known as an interchange fee. This generally flows from the
acquirer to the issuer as a percentage of the value of a transaction. Interchange allows
schemes, issuers, and acquirers to place different prices on cardholders and merchants
in a way that promotes the widest possible use and acceptance of a scheme’s product.
125. These prices need not be equal for both parties, and they can even be negative (i.e. a
party can be paid to use the product). This is generally determined by the maturity of
the scheme and the relative price sensitivities of consumers and merchants. The fact
that interchange generally flows from the acquiring bank (from merchants) to the
issuing bank (to subsidise use by cardholders) is seen by The European Central Bank
15
(ECB) as evidence that merchants are less price-sensitive with respect to the cost of
payment than consumers.
126. This means that merchant acceptance of card schemes will vary less in response to an
increase in the price of accepting payment than consumer use of card payments in
response to a change in the price they face. According to the ECB, this is due mainly to
the fact that accepting card payments has become a necessity for merchants in many
business sectors. Another way of explaining this is that merchants multi-home(i.e.
they feel the need to accept most forms of payment), whereas card-holders single-
home(i.e. most consumers choose the payment types that suit them best, rather than
holding a whole suite of cards). Therefore, increasing the price of acceptance to
merchants has a relatively small impact on acceptance, whereas reducing the price to
consumers can plausibly induce them to switch from one card brand or issuer to
another.
127. As explained in a 2012 paper
16
, without interchange, issuers and acquirers would both
set prices independently of each other in order to maximise their own profit. The paper
argues that without interchange, issuers would not take into account the externality
that attracting additional cardholders and card usage generates additional revenues for
the acquirer by increasing the number of card transactions. The issuer would therefore
15
Borestam, A., & Schmiedel, H. (2011). Interchange fees in card payments. Occasional Paper Series No.
131. Retrieved from https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/scpops/ecbocp131.pdf
16
Rysman, M., & Wright, J. (2012). The Economics of Payment Cards. Retrieved from
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2183420
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
36
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
tend to set its price to cardholders too high in terms of maximising the profits of the
system as a whole, resulting in fewer card transactions. There is also an externality in
the reverse direction, in that each additional merchant acquired will generate additional
transactions and revenue for the issuer.
17
128. This is not unique to retail payment systems. Interchange is a perfectly rational profit-
maximising mechanism from the perspective of a network owner where there is a two-
sided market. Actively balancing prices on both sides of the market is particularly
valuable when a network is first being built up. Another example of where an
interchange-like mechanism is used is the newspaper industry, in which the newspaper
must balance the cost of production between readers and advertisers, with much of the
cost falling on the latter in practice. While there is no explicit interchange fee in such a
situation, there is an internal transfer of value.
4 Do you agree with our explanation of the rationale for interchange?
Interchange in practice
129. In New Zealand, interchange is charged on virtually all Visa and MasterCard credit card
transactions. Since 2009, interchange caps have been set individually by the schemes (as
noted in Annex 2, prior to 2009, it was set collectively between each scheme and its
issuers). The schemes set a complex range of interchange caps depending on the
merchant type and the form of card used. For example, schemes set a lower interchange
cap for strategic merchants a handful of large merchants such as supermarkets and
fuel chains.
130. Schemes receive no revenue from the interchange fee this is passed from the acquirer
to the issuer.
131. Issuers are free to charge interchange below the cap. We understand that generally,
issuers charge the maximum allowable interchange, with two exceptions:
In the case of whole categories of ‘merchants’, such as charities, in which issuers
notify schemes that they wish to charge a lower rate of interchange (this is reflected
in the reported average weighted interchange figures).
When large merchants negotiate directly with the issuing side of the merchant’s
acquirer to have them charge a lower rate of interchange on transactions made by
the issuer’s customers with the merchant. This is distinct from merchant-scheme or
merchant-acquirer negotiations that may also take place (see below), and is not
captured in the interchange figures that have been provided to us. It is unclear how
often these negotiations actually result in lower interchange being applied.
18
132. While the two open credit card schemes appear to compete vigorously to attract issuers
and merchants, this competition appears to have the natural impact of increasing,
rather than decreasing, the interchange caps that are set by the schemes. This is
essentially because:
17
Whether interchange is still justifiable on this basis in a mature, near-ubiquitous market as with Visa
and MasterCard is contested in academic literature.
18
Issuers appear to have very little reason to agree to charge a lower rate of interchange. This is
because we understand that margins on acquiring services for large merchants are generally relatively
low. Therefore, there is little incentive for the issuer to reduce its revenue stream so that the acquirer
will win the merchant’s business. In fact, there is actually a disincentive on the issuer in that if the
merchant’s services were provided by another acquirer, then that acquirer would have to pay the issuer
the full interchange rate.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
37
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
Issuers prefer high interchange fees, because it makes it easier to attract cardholders
through greater rewards and inducements, and allows them to recoup the costs of
processing payments.
Acquirers prefer low interchange fees, because it makes it easier to attract
merchants.
As noted above, merchants appear to be less price sensitive than consumers in
regards to the cost of payment. This flows through to the sensitivity of issuers and
acquirers, to the point where the issuer is more sensitive to a decrease in
interchange than the acquirer is to an increase. Moreover, merchants are able to
pass costs through to consumers in the form of higher overall prices.
Most acquirers are also issuers, and therefore any increase in cost to an acquirer
through an increase in interchange is directly netted off as an increase in revenue to
the issuer (assuming no change in card usage). This means that the acquiring side of
an issuing bank is likely to be considerably less opposed to an increase in interchange
than a solo-acquirer (rare in New Zealand).
As markets mature and change, merchants become less price-sensitive to the cost of
accepting payment as consumer demand to use a particular payment method
increases. This makes it relatively more attractive to increase interchange to attract
additional cardholders, rather than decrease it to attract additional merchants.
133. The level of competitive constraint on interchange caps will ultimately depend on
merchants’ willingness to pay the resulting MSF (see below). This in turn depends on
how close consumers see other forms of payment as substitutes. For example, the
declining use of proprietary EFTPOS cards would suggest that consumers now see it as
less of a substitute for scheme products than previously, and there are seemingly no
mainstream ‘direct entry’ payment options on the immediate horizon to compete with
scheme products in the card-present context.
5 Have we accurately described the incentives on parties in relation to interchange?
Credit interchange rates
134. Current interchange caps are published publicly on the website of Visa and MasterCard,
although a record of the changes over time (or the effective rate, where this differs from
the cap) is not. As an illustration of the broad range of interchange categories available,
Table 5 outlines the interchange rates applicable to Visa credit and debit cards, as at
May 2016.
19
Of note is the significantly higher interchange cap that is applicable to Visa
Platinum as opposed to Visa Classic or Visa Gold cards for electronic and standard
transactions (which was adjusted up in 2015 from 1.85 to 2.1 per cent). This arguably
creates a significant incentive for issuers to steer customers towards premium credit
cards.
19
Visa New Zealand (n.d.). Interchange. Retrieved from
http://www.visa.co.nz/aboutvisa/interchange/interchange.shtml
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
38
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
Table 5: Interchange rates applicable to Visa credit and debit cards (May 2016)
Credit Debit
Fee Program
Visa Classic
Visa Gold
Visa
Platinum
Visa
Signature
Visa
Commercial
Visa
Consumer
Visa
Commercial
Industry Program Charities 0.39%
Strategic Merchants Card Present
(CP)Rate 1
0.50% $0.04
Strategic Merchants CP Rate 2 0.55% $0.05
Strategic Merchants Card Not
Present (CNP) Rate 1
0.50%
Strategic Merchants CNP Rate 2 0.55%
Strategic Merchants CP and CNP
(Credit) and CNP (Debit) Rate 3
0.60% 0.60%
Strategic Merchants CP and CNP
(Credit) and CNP (Debit) Rate 4
0.70% 0.70%
Strategic Merchants CP and CNP
(Credit) and CNP (Debit) Rate 5
0.80% 0.80%
Strategic Merchants CP and CNP
(Credit) and CNP (Debit) Rate 6
0.98% 0.98%
Industry Program Government,
Utilities & Telecom
NZ$0.70 NZ$0.70
Industry Program Insurance NZ$1.00 NZ$1.00
Industry Program Recurring
Payments
0.70% 0.70%
Electronic (CP) 0.85%
2.10% 2.30% 2.00%
0.30%
Standard (CNP) 1.25% 1.25% 2.00%
135. One scheme has provided data which shows that the average weighted interchange
charged for credit was relatively flat between 2009 and 2015, before rising modestly in
2016. Another scheme provided us with data showing that of the 11 changes it had
made to credit interchange rates since March 2014, 9 of them were decreases.
However, this does not necessarily reflect the direction of change for overall weighted-
average interchange.
136. We have also been provided with data by a bank which shows that between 2012 and
2015, for its merchant base:
Overall weighted average interchange fees for (open) credit cards increased by
around 9 per cent.
Credit interchange rates charged to acquirers of small merchants increased by
around 16 per cent.
Credit interchange rates charged to acquirers of strategic merchants (generally the
largest merchants, such as supermarket and petrol station chains) decreased by
around 20 per cent. We understand that this was as a result of direct pressure placed
on schemes by large merchants, following a reduction in the rebates received from
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
39
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
acquirers on expiry of the settlement with the Commerce Commission in 2013 (see
below).
137. For this acquirer, the effect of these changes is that interchange charged for small
merchants is now around two and a half times the interchange charged for strategic
merchants.
6
Why are interchange rates falling for large merchants but increasing for small-medium
merchants?
138. Overall, the data we have received from banks and schemes tells a similar story while
weighted average interchange rates fluctuate, and growth is not rapid, the trend is up,
rather than down.
139. There is no interchange on closed credit cards such as American Express. This is because
American Express is both the issuer and acquirer. Nevertheless, American Express still
implicitly replicates an interchange fee by balancing the charges it places on cardholders
and merchants in order to maximise profits.
Interchange for debit transactions
140. Card-not-present and contactless scheme debit transactions work under the same
interchange business model as credit transactions. Interchange fees for card-not-present
and contactless scheme debit transactions are generally lower than the equivalent credit
interchange rate. Contactless debit interchange was justified by schemes on the basis of
the significant investment that the development of the technology required.
Nevertheless, the interchange cap has been falling over time, largely to encourage
merchant acceptance in the context of merchants continuing to face no direct cost from
inserted and swiped debit transactions.
141. Data provided by a bank shows that average debit interchange for its merchant mix fell
significantly between 2012 and 2015. Much of this decrease is seemingly attributable to
the shift from debit interchange being applied only to card-not-present (online)
transactions, to it also being applied (at a lower rate) to contactless transactions as their
uptake increased.
Acquirer-merchant relationships
Structure of merchant service fees
142. Merchant service fees (MSFs) are a key feature of payment options that operate under
the interchange business model (credit cards and contactless and card-not-present
scheme debit transactions). Acquiring banks collect MSFs from merchants to pay for
scheme fees (see below), switch fees, float costs (the cost of paying a merchant before
the issuer reimburses the acquirer), merchant servicing costs, as well as a bank margin.
Most importantly, however, the MSF covers the interchange fee paid to the issuing
bank. Stakeholders consistently told us that around 70 to 80 per cent of the MSF is paid
out as interchange. As discussed above, no MSF is charged on switch-to-issuer (domestic
rails) transactions and there is no associated interchange fee.
143. Prior to the Commission’s 2009 settlement (see Annex 2), we understand that most
acquirers simply provided merchants with one ‘blended’ MSF, which averaged out the
cost of accepting various payment types into a fixed percentage per transaction,
regardless of the mix of cards used in a particular month. These blended MSF
percentages are fixed for a given period of time.
144. As part of the 2009 settlement, acquirers are also required to offer merchants:
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
40
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
Unblended MSFs, which are separate fees for Visa and MasterCard transactions,
enabling merchants to see the cost of accepting each scheme’s credit cards.
Unbundled MSFs, which are separate fees for all types of Visa and MasterCard
transactions, allowing merchants to see the cost of accepting every type of card.
145. In practice, acquirers differ in the bundling options that they provide to merchants. For
example, one bank told us that it splits out credit and debit merchant service fees by
default, whereas other banks do not. Unbundling is known as cost-plus pricing, in that
acquirers pass along the interchange fee that they are charged, with a margin built on
top.
146. All of the banks that we spoke to told us that they prefer to unbundle. This is likely
because, when an acquirer sets a bundled rate, it does so based on the estimated mix of
high- and low-cost transactions that a merchant will process. Unbundling avoids the risk
for a bank that a merchant will process a greater proportion of high-cost transactions
than anticipated.
147. There has not been great uptake of unbundling by merchants banks have told us that
only around 5 per cent of merchants choose to unbundle. This is likely to be because
unbundled rates are more difficult for all but the largest merchants to understand, and
because unbundling creates greater cost uncertainty for merchants. We spoke to a
range of merchants and noted that while some of the largest merchants had the
capacity and financial incentive to understand MSFs, many others did not. Retail New
Zealand noted that many smaller merchants would not take the time to unpick MSFs, as
these costs are only one of many costs they face.
Level of merchant service fees
148. Based on information about MSFs provided to us by a bank, we estimate that the total
cost of MSFs to merchants in 2015 from transactions made on scheme rails was $461
million.
20
In addition, Retail New Zealand has conducted surveys of its members’ MSFs in
2014 and 2015. According to its survey, which was weighted by industry sector (but not
necessarily representative of the economy as a whole), merchants faced an average MSF
in 2014 of 1 per cent for contactless debit and 1.4 per cent for Visa and MasterCard
credit. In the 2015 survey, merchants’ average MSF for contactless debit remained at 1
per cent, with the MSF for credit rising to 1.7 per cent.
21
These figures somewhat exceed
those provided to us by banks in both their rate and level of growth between 2014 and
2015. Using the Retail New Zealand figures, total MSFs in 2015 would have been closer
to $589 million.
149. Based on information provided to us by a bank, headline average MSFs appear to track
closely to changes in interchange, with a modest rise in MSFs over the last three years in
line with a growth in weighted average interchange. In line with this, headline acquirer
margins have seemingly remained relatively constant. However, we understand that
these figures do not tell the full story. Some banks provide merchants with rebates to
attract or retain them as a customer and these rebates are not factored into the
20
Covec estimated that the total cost of MSFs to merchants in 2015 was $373 million, however this is in
2010 dollars, and utilises different sector coverage figures and MSF assumptions.
21
These figures include merchants who pay the same bundled MSF for debit and credit, so a merchant
receiving an unbundled MSF would generally face a lower contactless rate, and higher credit rate, than
the reported averages.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
41
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
headline MSF figures. However, we understand that rebate levels have reduced since
2013, potentially increasing acquirer margins.
22
150. Any competition that occurs between acquirers for merchants is seemingly restricted to
the acquiring margin, with the interchange rate charged by the issuer acting as a
relatively hard floor for overall MSFs.
23
151. A consistent theme of our discussions with stakeholders was the gap between the MSFs
faced by large and small merchants. This appears to be largely a function of the differing
interchange caps set by schemes, with much lower caps set for strategic merchants than
for smaller merchants. However, as will be discussed later (see Section 4.4), while
interchange caps for strategic and non-strategic merchants are diverging, this is not
necessarily leading to a divergence in MSFs to the same extent.
152. Despite the higher MSFs that smaller merchants face, they are in some cases able to
negotiate discounts. For example, Retail New Zealand has negotiated a (seemingly
modest) reduction in MSFs for its members with Westpac of 1.49 per cent where
transactions exceed $150 on average, 1.64 per cent where transactions are below $150
on average, and 1.79 per cent for card-not-present transactions. However, this rate is
limited in that it only applies to bundled fees.
153. A final complicating factor is the introduction of contactless debit, and its associated
MSF. Because the interchange and associated MSF for contactless debit is generally
lower than for credit, the growth of contactless transactions (and the inclusion of
contactless debit in the bundled figure) can, in some instances, give the impression that
bundled MSFs are falling. However in reality, the total amount paid in MSFs is
increasing. This is because contactless debit payments have replaced proprietary EFTPOS
and cash, which do not attract a MSF.
154. Closed credit card schemes such as American Express also charge merchants a MSF for
accepting their cards (in this case, directly). The business model of American Express
differs slightly from those of Visa and MasterCard. It charges a higher MSF on the
premise that it provides merchants with higher-value consumers than its competitors,
among other benefits. As a result, merchant acceptance of American Express and other
closed credit cards is significantly lower than for open credit cards, and mostly limited to
larger merchants.
155. American Express charges a flat rate to merchants, regardless of the type of American
Express card used. Nevertheless, American Express does differentiate its MSFs between
merchants, depending on relative bargaining power and (relatedly) the level of value
that a merchant considers that American Express provides.
3.2.4 Scheme-merchant relationships
156. The situation in respect of MSFs is further complicated by the direct negotiation that
occurs between schemes and a handful of large merchants regarding credit cards and
contactless scheme debit. Under these negotiations, these merchants receive an
additional rebate off their MSF, in addition to the lower base interchange rates that they
face as a ‘strategic’ merchant (as shown in Table 5 above). In return, schemes may
22
The Commerce Commission’s 2009 settlement, which expired in 2013, required banks to reduce the
weighted-average interchange fee that was applied overall. Banks chose to comply with this by giving
rebates to merchants.
23
As noted above, merchants have the ability to negotiate directly with issuers to seek to reduce the
interchange charged on transactions at their businesses. However the extent to which this actually
results in lower interchange rates being applied is unclear.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
42
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
impose conditions on merchants, such as agreeing not to surcharge for a period of time,
or agreeing to enable contactless payment. These agreements are not in breach of the
Commission’s 2009 settlement because they are not a ‘standard contracting procedure’.
They are also not taken into account in the published interchange rates.
3.2.5 Customer-merchant relationships
157. Merchants are able to influence the payment option a consumer uses by:
Surcharging, where merchants add an additional fee for particular payment options
to recoup the cost of accepting payment without passing on an overall price increase
(and thereby sending more accurate price signals to the consumers).
Steering, which means not accepting (or discouraging) some forms of payment, or
preventing a payment type being used in some circumstances (such as low-value
transactions) if it is generally accepted.
Surcharging
158. The prevalence of surcharging by merchants for switch-to-acquirer transactions is
relatively low in New Zealand. In a 2012 survey of merchants, less than 10 per cent
(weighted by turnover) reported surcharging customers for credit card payments.
24
Similarly, in Retail New Zealand’s 2016 survey of its members, almost none of the
respondents reported charging their customers extra for the use of certain payment
methods. Nevertheless, there are some sectors in which surcharging for credit and card-
not-present debit is more prevalent. These include hotels, airlines, and central and local
government. We are unaware of any merchant that surcharges for contactless debit
payments.
159. Historically, there appear to have been four main barriers to surcharging:
Prior to the Commerce Commission’s 2009 settlement, the schemes imposedno
surcharge rules’, which prohibited surcharging of credit card transactions by
merchants. American Express, which was not part of the settlement, still prohibits
surcharging by merchants, although its success in enforcing this condition is
seemingly limited.
Surcharging can be technically difficult. While we understand that many terminals
can now detect the type of card being used, this still needs to be linked into the
merchant’s POS system, or otherwise the surcharge will need to be manually applied.
Lack of information about the cost of accepting different payment types. Because
merchant uptake of unbundling is low (for whatever reason), many merchants will
not have enough information about the cost of accepting different cards from their
bank or the scheme to be able to make an informed decision about whether they
should surcharge and if they do, at what rate.
Customers react negatively to surcharging. An Australian survey sponsored by
American Express
25
found that 93 per cent of consumers wanted surcharges
24
Commerce Commission (2013). Evaluation of the 2009 interchange and credit card settlements.
Retrieved from
http://www.comcom.govt.nz/business-competition/enforcement-response-register-
commerce/investigation-reports/research-report-evaluation-of-the-2009-interchange-and-credit-card-
settlements
25
RDG Insights. (2015). Every Good Buy is the Next Hello. Retrieved from
http://www.retaildoctor.com.au/wp-content/uploads/2015/03/RDG-Insights-Payment-Surcharges-
Report_03032015.pdf.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
43
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
removed, 43 per cent left with a bad impression of the business that surcharged
them, and 25 per cent claimed that they would not return to a business that
surcharged them. While these sorts of opinions are not necessarily reflected in actual
behaviour
26
, this sort of customer reaction made all of the merchants we spoke to
incredibly reluctant to surcharge, for fear of being the first mover and thereby losing
significant business. As a result, stakeholders we spoke to noted that surcharging is
often most prevalent in sectors where merchants have some degree of market
power.
Steering
160. In contrast, a reasonable portion of merchants steer in relation to switch-to-acquirer
(scheme rails) transactions. One bank that we spoke to told us that around 25 per cent
of their merchant customers did not accept credit. Another, which has a higher
proportion of small merchants as customers, placed non-acceptance of credit cards by
their merchants in the region of 40 per cent.
161. These figures may, however, understate the level of credit card acceptance, and
therefore the countervailing power of merchants in respect of MSFs and interchange.
For example, when weighted by volume, a 2012 survey of merchants
27
found that
around 85 per cent accepted Visa or MasterCard credit cards. Nevertheless, nearly 50
per cent did not accept American Express, and more than 60 per cent did not accept
Diners Club.
162. Because schemes still impose honour-all-cards rules (see Annex 2), merchants who
accept a scheme’s credit cards are not allowed to steer customers away from high-cost
cards, towards low-cost credit cards.
163. Merchants also steer by not accepting contactless debit. Our understanding is that only
around 30 per cent of merchants accept contactless payment, although this is growing,
and likely to be significantly higher when weighted by volume.
3.2.6 Scheme relationship with banks (as issuers and acquirers)
164. While schemes do not see any revenue from interchange, they instead receive revenue
from issuers and acquirers for the use of scheme debit and credit cards. The exact
business model underlying the flows, and the value of these flows, is not public.
Nevertheless, our understanding is that:
Issuers pay schemes a service fee in proportion to the number and value of
transactions that take place on their cards.
In some instances issuers receive a rebate from a scheme, for example, if they solely
offer that scheme’s products, or undertake programmes that increase the volume of
transactions that are processed on that scheme’s rails.
Issuers receive a rebate from a scheme if they increase the volume of transactions
that are processed on a scheme’s cards.
Acquirers pay a fixed scheme processing fee per transaction and a fee based on the
value of transactions they process.
26
According to figures from IKEA, the introduction of surcharging for credit in the UK simply led to a
near one-for-one replacement of credit transactions with debit transactions. See Symons, C. (2012).
Submission to Canadian Competition Tribunal. Retrieved from
http://www.ct-tc.gc.ca/CMFiles/CT-2010-
010_Witness%20Statement%20of%20Charles%20Symons_229_45_3-13-2012_6999.pdf
27
Commerce Commission (2013). Evaluation of the 2009 interchange and credit card settlements.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
44
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
165. The monetary flows between schemes, issuers and acquirers therefore mean that both
schemes and issuers have incentives to increase card usage so that more revenue can be
collected. Nevertheless, in theory, competition in these markets should constrain the
per-transaction revenues of the schemes, at least from issuers. This is because issuers
have a choice over which scheme’s products they offer. Of the five major banks, just two
(ANZ and BNZ) offer both Visa and MasterCard credit cards, while none offer both Visa
and MasterCard debit cards. Therefore, if scheme fees to issuers were to increase,
issuers could threaten to only offer the other scheme’s products.
166. There may be less competitive pressure in the scheme-acquirer market. This is because,
since the 1990s, in order to attract merchants, all banks have acquired transactions from
both schemes.
28
Therefore, any threat to not acquire a scheme’s transactions following
an increase in scheme fees may have limited credibility. Nevertheless, schemes are likely
to face some limit in their ability to profitably raise their fees to acquirers. This is
because, assuming these costs are a passed on to merchants, any increase in the MSF
will have a (possibly small) negative effect on merchant acceptance.
Ancillary relationships 3.3
3.3.1 Switch relationships with banks (as issuers and acquirers)
167. As noted above, most transactions are ‘switched’ by either Paymark or Verifone New
Zealand. Both charge a per-transaction fee to either the issuer (for switch-to-issuer
transactions) or acquirer (for switch-to-acquirer transactions). Verifone’s switch was
initially operated by ANZ (branded as EFTPOS NZ), before being sold to Verifone in 2013.
Currently Verifone is only able to process transactions where the merchant’s acquirer is
ANZ, although Verifone is trying to gain access to process transactions for merchants
who acquire with BNZ, Westpac and ASB. Schemes also have the ability to process some
transactions directly, bypassing a switch, but we understand that the vast majority of
transactions still pass through a domestic switch.
168. There are a number of entities, known as payment gateways, that complement or
substitute for Paymark and Verifone for card-not-present transactions. In New Zealand,
Payment Express handles many web-based transactions. Other competitors include
Paymark’s Click service, Paystation, and Swipe. In addition to online payments, these
systems also facilitate manual (e.g. mail order) processing of credit card payments. For
online payments, these switches also act as the customer interface.
3.3.2 Switch-merchant relationships
169. Merchants also face a nominal fee to be connected to a switch, regardless of payment
types or volumes. This connection is required for the merchant to accept any type of
electronic card. For example, Paymark charges $13.50 a month per terminal, capped at
five terminals per store. Competition over these charges is likely to be similar to
competition in the switch-issuer and switch-acquirer markets. We do not consider this
flow to be central to the system and therefore do not discuss it further.
3.3.3 Merchant-terminal provider relationships
170. In addition to the MSFs that merchants pay to acquirers, merchants with a physical
presence also face separate costs for using the physical payment hardware that provides
a customer interface. These terminals are required regardless of which payment cards
the merchant chooses to accept. Merchants may either purchase a terminal (for in the
28
Prior to this, merchants may have needed to have a relationship with multiple acquiring banks if they
wanted to accept cards processed by both schemes.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
45
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
region of $1,000) or hire a terminal for a monthly fee. In some cases, merchants have
the option of paying a per-transaction fee to the terminal provider in return for a lower
monthly rate. There are, anecdotally, at least 80 terminal providers in New Zealand.
171. Payments New Zealand requires all terminals to comply with various security standards.
This means that merchants are required to replace their terminals every few years.
Some of the stakeholders we spoke argued that the requirement to upgrade terminals
was an unnecessary additional cost for merchants. However, the cost of terminals seems
to be a relatively small component of retail payment systems as a whole.
Resource costs 3.4
172. This section has examined the fees and inducements that support the business models
of retail payment systems. It has not, however, outlined the underlying costs that
different participants face regardless of whether there is an explicit fee or charge
associated with a particular method of payment. To do so is difficult because most of
the data required to determine this is not public, and no work has been done to
estimate these costs in New Zealand.
173. Nevertheless, staff at the Reserve Bank of Australia
29
(RBA) have attempted to calculate
the ‘resource cost’ of various methods of payment – that is, the economic resources
expended by the various system participants to ‘produce’ a payment. This includes
factors such as fraud prevention, authorisation and transaction processing, tender time
at the point of sale, and other back-office costs. Crucially, this measure does not account
for transfers between parties, such as rewards or merchant service fees. While these are
private benefits and costs, they are not a cost to the system as a whole.
Figure 10: Australian resource costs by transaction value (RBA data, Australian
dollars)
29
Stewart et al (2014). The Evolution of Payment Costs in Australia. Retrieved from:
http://www.rba.gov.au/publications/rdp/2014/pdf/rdp2014-14.pdf
$0.00
$0.10
$0.20
$0.30
$0.40
$0.50
$0.60
$0.70
$0.80
$0.90
$1.00
$0 $20 $40 $60 $80 $100
Credit cards (inserted/swiped) Credit cards (contactless)
Scheme debit (inserted/swiped) Scheme debit (contactless)
Proprietary EFTPOS Cash (high estimate)
Cash (low estimate)
Average NZ electronic transaction size ($AU)
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
46
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
174. Figure 10 shows the RBA staff’s estimates of resource costs for various payment
methods, and how they differ based on differing transaction values (some resource
costs are fixed, while others are variable with the transaction amount). Applying these
cost estimates to the average electronic transaction size in New Zealand in 2016 ($50
approximately AU$47), yields the following resource costs (converted into New Zealand
dollars):
Cash: NZ$0.55 (1.1 per cent of transaction value).
Australian EFTPOS: NZ$0.48 (0.96 per cent).
Credit cards: NZ$0.81 (1.62 per cent).
Contactless credit: NZ$0.70 (1.40 per cent).
Scheme debit cards: NZ$0.76 (1.52 per cent).
Contactless debit: NZ$0.63 (1.26 per cent).
175. The dashed lines in Figure 10 are for contactless transactions. The lower resource cost
for contactless cards is due to reduced tender time for the merchants at the point of
sale.
176. If we assume that New Zealand has a similar level of inherent resource costs to
Australia, this would suggest that the cost to process an average-sized ($50) electronic
transaction via credit card is around two-thirds higher than the cost of processing an
EFTPOS transaction. Based on current transaction volumes, we estimate that the total
resource costs of processing card payments to the New Zealand system is around $950
million annually.
30
177. In fact, there is reason to believe that the difference in cost between credit and our
EFTPOS system is actually greater. This is because, at the time the RBA’s study was
undertaken, Australia’s system relied on a relatively costly system of bilateral linkages
between banks. This is in contrast to New Zealand, and what is generally considered to
be our more efficient system of switching based around Paymark (and to a lesser extent
Verifone). We understand that Australia has since implemented a more efficient,
centralised EFTPOS system.
7
Is the resource cost data robust? Is the Australian data likely to over-state or under-state
the costs of running New Zealand payment systems?
30
This takes data provided to us by a switch about the volumes of different types of transactions and
multiplies them by the resource cost per average-sized transaction from the RBA study. This may
underestimate the resource cost in that we know that credit card transactions are, on average,
considerably larger than debit transactions and would therefore incur a higher resource cost than is
calculated based on the average overall transaction size. On the other hand, use of Australian data
about the cost of proprietary EFTPOS may overstate the resource cost of proprietary EFTPOS
transactions in New Zealand.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
47
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
4. Issues identified
Overview 4.1
178. We have identified a number of issues in both the credit and debit card markets. Many
of these issues result from the interchange business model operating in New Zealand.
179. We consider that there are two main issues in the credit card market, where the
interchange business model is resulting in:
Issue 1: Economic inefficiency of $45 million dollars of additional cost annually as a
result of the induced usage of the relatively more expensive credit card network.
Issue 2: Increased prices for all consumers (estimated at $187 million annually) to
fund credit card rewards, with mainly higher-income consumers benefiting from
those rewards.
180. The basis for these calculations is outlined in the remainder of this section, and in Annex
4.
181. This is the result of the fact that consumers do not face accurate price signals, and leads
to overall higher costs for consumers. These issues are long-standing, although there is
some evidence that these inefficiencies have been growing in recent years as a result of
the premiumisation of credit cards.
182. Similar issues are developing in the debit market, where the interchange business model
is now competing with “free” debit transactions (EFTPOS and inserted or swiped scheme
debit).
Issue 3: Given the dynamics of the interchange business model, the inefficiencies and
wealth transfers of the credit card market could also emerge in the debit market.
Issue 4: There may be technical or institutional barriers to entry or expansion for new
debit payment products.
183. The size of the issues in the debit market is difficult to quantify at this stage. This is
because recent technological developments could allow for significant retail payments
innovation. The timing and scale of any new developments are difficult to predict.
184. The interchange business model is also impacting on small and medium enterprises
(SMEs) in both markets:
Issue 5: The gap between merchant service fees paid by large (“strategic”) merchants
and others is significant and seemingly growing, reducing the competitiveness of
smaller businesses. The lack of pricing and cost transparency may be reducing the
ability of these businesses to negotiate better fees with acquiring banks and make
decisions about which payment options to accept and whether to surcharge.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
48
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
The interchange business model is resulting in inefficient 4.2
outcomes in the credit card market
4.2.1 Consumers do not face accurate price signals…
185. We consider that the incentives faced by all market participants – consumers,
merchants, issuers, acquirers and schemes lead to a greater use of credit cards relative
to other payment options, compared to a situation in which these incentives did not
exist. Fundamentally, consumers’ choices between payment options are distorted by the
incentives placed on them by card issuers and merchants. This means that, in making
their decisionswhile acting completely rationally and in their best interest at an
individual level consumers do not face or take into account the system-wide costs and
benefits of various payment options.
186. As noted in Section 2.1, credit cards offer benefits to both consumers and merchants,
allowing consumers to spend when they do not have cash on hand and allowing
merchants to accept payment from a larger pool of potential customers (particularly
international consumers). We do not dispute this, and these benefits are justifiably
reflected in the existence of a price placed on merchants for credit card transactions.
The question explored in the remainder of this section is whether the incentives in the
system distort this price beyond what is efficient.
187. Ordinarily, it is not the role of government to second-guess how consumers choose to
spend. In general, we assume that transactions only take place if both the buyer and the
seller consider themselves to benefit from the transaction. We also generally assume
that this decision is made in the absence of significant externalities, and therefore the
private costs and benefits to the consumer are close to the system-wide costs and
benefits.
188. This is not the case when a consumer selects a payment option. Due to the flow of
interchange, in many cases consumers do not face anywhere near the full cost of their
payment choice. This is because, as discussed in Section 3:
More than 70 per cent of credit card spend now earns rewards, and a growing
proportion of credit cards are ‘premium’ cards, which attract a higher interchange
rate and MSF. These rewards can be a significant incentive to use a particular card, in
addition to other financial benefits provided to credit card users, such as an interest-
free period.
These rewards are substantially funded through interchange, rather than annual
fees. This means that the cost of using a credit card can be negative for a cardholder.
That is, many credit card holders are effectively paid to use their card.
Few merchants surcharge, meaning that the costs a merchant faces in accepting
payment are averaged out across all consumers.
189. The lack of price signals to cardholders is a problem because it leads to:
Higher costs for processing retail transactions than would likely be the case if clear
price signals did exist (and consumers responded to these signals).
A redistribution of wealth from users of low-cost payment methods to those who
receive rewards.
Higher overall costs of goods and services as a result of the costs merchants face in
accepting payment.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
49
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
190. The overall process is referred to in the economic literature as “price coherence and
adverse intermediation”
31
. In such markets, intermediaries (schemes and banks) can
charge fees to merchants to incentivise consumers (through rewards) to use their
service (credit cards). Cardholders then switch to using higher-cost cards, with increased
costs ultimately borne by all consumers. This system works because the financial
incentives to cardholders are large enough to effectively motivate their choice of
payment option. These financial incentives are funded by a wider base (all consumers)
through slightly higher overall prices on all goods which are difficult to detect (and
therefore do not influence cardholders decisions).
4.2.2 which results in higher costs to process retail transactions
191. As noted in Section 3.4, the RBA found that the resource cost of a scheme credit card
transaction is roughly two-thirds higher than the cost of an EFTPOS transaction,
excluding the cost of credit and rewards. If we assume that New Zealand has a similar
ratio of costs between payment methods to Australia, we estimate that the use of credit
cards instead of proprietary EFTPOS adds $137 million in costs to the New Zealand
economy annually.
32
Even though it is not borne by consumers in direct costs, these
costs will be passed onto consumers in higher overall prices.
192. It could be argued that this outcome is efficient by default because it is the result of
market participants’ decisions. However, we know from Section 3.2.2 that a high
proportion of consumers pay their credit card account balance before it attracts any
interest, and that around 40 per cent choose credit cards primarily for the rewards they
attract. For these rewards-focused consumers, credit card transactions are not made for
the credit itself, which might justify the greater resource cost to the system; rather, the
credit option is used to attract the financial benefit attached to using the premium card.
Extra resource cost is incurred in putting through these credit card transactions, with no
overall benefit to the economy, just a transfer of rewards to the individual consumer.
Therefore, a conservative estimate of the added cost to the economy that arises from
the use of credit cards by this 40 per cent is $45 million annually.
33
193. Put another way, 40 per cent of credit card users have no need for the credit; they have
sufficient funds in their accounts to pay for the purchases. However, they use their cards
because they are incentivised to do so through rewards and do not face the full cost of
doing so, since surcharging is uncommon. This individually rational behaviour then leads
to system-wide inefficiencies.
8
Do you agree with the logic underpinning our assessment that there is inefficiency in the
credit card market?
31
Edelman and Wright. (2014). Price coherence and adverse intermediation. Retrieved from
http://www.hbs.edu/faculty/Publication%20Files/14-052_41d72e17-7ca8-4090-99eb-a7d24e8eaa0f.pdf
32
This is distinct from the estimated $461-589 million in MSFs that merchants face to accept payment.
MSFs can exceed resource costs in some instances, as resource costs ignore transfers (most notably
rewards) and profit margins, while in the case of proprietary EFTPOS, the resource cost exceeds the
(zero) MSF.
33
We assume that around 20% of credit card transactions are made by business or international
cardholders, and have removed these from the analysis on the basis these transactions are unlikely to
have been induced by rewards. The $45 million represents around 0.13 per cent of the total value of
expenditure on credit cards in the year to March 2016.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
50
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
4.2.3 and higher overall prices for consumers
194. Competition between issuers for consumers through rewards programmes results in
upwards pressure on interchange fees paid by merchants, which are in turn passed onto
all consumers as higher prices for all goods and services. We estimate that the presence
of credit card rewards increase prices of goods and services for consumers by $187
million per annum. This is just a portion of the fees paid by merchants.
195. Higher prices are faced by all consumers, as a result of the low prevalence of surcharging
by merchants. If surcharging occurred, merchants would not have to factor the cost of
electronic transactions into the general prices because they would be recovered directly
from each customer depending on payment method used in each case.
4.2.4 …although these higher prices can be partially or fully offset for consumers
who receive credit card rewards
196. The increase in costs faced by consumers can be offset for the holders of rewards-
offering credit cards, who in some cases may receive rewards that greatly exceed the
overall increase in price that they face. On the other hand, those who do not hold
rewards-offering credit cards face an increase in price, with no corresponding benefit.
This represents a wealth transfer from the users of low-cost payment options to users of
high-cost cards.
197. This wealth transfer is strongly regressive. This is because users of high-cost credit cards
are likely to be on high incomes due either to issuer rules (for example, the Air New
Zealand American Express Platinum Card has a minimum income requirement of
$65,000), or self-selection as a result of higher-annual fees (that nevertheless do not
cover the full cost of rewards). In contrast, the cost that merchants face is passed on to
all consumers, including those on low incomes. Our rough estimate is that this results in
an ongoing cross-subsidy from low-income households to high-income households of
$59 million per annum.
34
9
Do you agree with the logic underpinning our assessment that reward schemes result in
higher overall prices and cross-subsidies?
Box 2: Are payment system cross-subsidies worse than any other cross-subsidy?
A repeated theme in our discussion with stakeholders was that, while credit card rewards
likely result in a cross-subsidy from users of low-cost cards to users of high-cost cards, there
are a range of cross-subsidies that exist across the economy. Stakeholders argued that cross-
subsidies that occur in retail payments are fundamentally no different to those that might
exist in respect of loyalty schemes (such as FlyBuys), petrol rebates, free car parking, or the
cost of labour on weekends.
We agree that cross-subsidies are prevalent across the economy. While cross-subsidies may
be allocatively inefficient, they can be valued by consumers, and are clearly profit-enhancing
34
In arriving at this figure, we assume that 10% of credit card transactions are made by international
cardholders, and remove them from the analysis. We include business cardholders in the analysis. We
assume that 75% of credit card spending attracts rewards, that the average value of rewards is 1% of
expenditure, that 20% of rewards are funded through annual fees, that only the highest-earning 40% of
households earn rewards, and that these households are responsible for 68% of retail expenditure. The
$59 million figure represents around 0.17 per cent of the total value of expenditure on credit cards in
the year to March 2016.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
51
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
for firms that introduce them. Nevertheless, it is not uncommon for firms to seek to
minimise them. For example, surcharging on public holidays is becoming more common.
Cross-subsidies associated with credit card rewards can be distinguished from other cross-
subsidies in two main ways:
Firstly, card payments are pervasive across the economy in a way that few, if any,
other cross-subsidies are. Individual businesses may offer free car parking to their
consumers, or pay staff more to work on weekends without surcharging. However,
the cross-subsidy in relation to card payments essentially extends to any merchant
who accepts a credit card payment.
Secondly, when businesses cross-subsidise a product or service, they generally make
an active decision to do so. For example, a business that decides to offer FlyBuys
does so knowing that it will have to charge extra to all of its customers to pay for the
benefits that those who utilise the reward scheme receive. In contrast, a merchant
is not a participant in the decision-making around the cost of rewards that are
embedded in their MSF. Therefore, because rewards are tied to the payment
method, a merchant cannot choose to accept credit card payments without also
accepting the higher-cost cards that also provide rewards.
4.2.5 These issues are unlikely be resolved by market mechanisms
198. There are several ways that the lack of price signals could theoretically be resolved
through market mechanisms. One way is through increased surcharging for expensive
payment methods by merchants. However, as alluded to in Section 3.2.6, merchants in a
competitive market face a significant first-mover disadvantage through a negative
customer reaction if they introduce surcharges, making it unlikely that surcharging will
become significantly more widespread. Box 3 explores the possibility of surcharging
further.
Box 3: Is surcharging the solution?
Accurate surcharging for the use of higher-cost payment options would reduce the impact of
premium card rewards. This is because a surcharge at every purchase would negate any
benefit that would accrue to the premium card holder over and above what is the intrinsic
value of using that payment option. A consumer would only choose to use a payment option
that attracted a surcharge if they valued the benefits (such as the credit or contactless
function) more than the cost.
However, Section 3.2.5 outlined that merchants face technical and customer experience
barriers to surcharging. There are also challenges in accurate pricing in the first place. This is
because merchants do not face prices for each payment option on the same basis. In New
Zealand, acquiring banks charge merchants for costs associated with credit transactions and
contactless scheme debit transactions, but not for EFTPOS or contacted scheme debit
transactions. Nor do merchants face all of the costs associated with cash. This means that
any menu of surcharges based on these costs would not send accurate price signals to
consumers; they would act as rough proxies at best.
The use of discounts is a possible alternative to surcharging. While theoretically equivalent,
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
52
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
and psychologically more acceptable to consumers, discounting is potentially less effective
at influencing behaviour
35
, can make merchants’ headline prices look less competitive than
those who don’t discount, and presents similar implementation issues to surcharging.
199. Another way of providing consumers with accurate price signals would be for issuers to
increase annual fees to more closely reflect the benefit received by cardholders.
However, in a (seemingly) competitive market between issuers for consumers, there is
little incentive to do so when it would discourage consumers from choosing their
product, and when there is already a substantial flow of income from interchange to
fund rewards.
36
This means that we see it as highly unlikely that unilateral action by
issuers will correct the price signals to consumers in the foreseeable future.
200. If the inaccurate price signals cannot be corrected for directly, the extent of the
inaccuracy could at least be reduced if merchants or acquirers had greater ability to
negotiate down interchange and MSFs. Section 3.2.3 outlined the reasons why acquirers
that form part of issuing banks have limited incentive to negotiate down interchange
rates. In addition, Box 4 explores the reasons that self-acquirers are also unlikely to act
as a countervailing force on interchange.
Box 4: Will self-acquirers place downward pressure on interchange?
The Commission’s 2009 settlement (see Annex 2) allowed for entities to become acquirers
of card transactions without also being card issuers or financial institutions. In theory, this
has the potential to place downward pressure on interchange fees, because self-acquirers
are likely to be significantly more averse to an increase in interchange fees than combined
issuer-acquirers (see Section 3.2.3).
In practice, it is unlikely that the provision for self-acquiring has had any material impact on
interchange rates. We are only aware of one merchant that self-acquires in New Zealand:
Countdown. It informed us that becoming a self-acquirer required a substantial investment
that was only viable due to two reasons. Firstly, Countdown had the ability to leverage off
infrastructure developed by its parent company, Woolworths Australia. Secondly, self-
acquirers formerly faced a significant financial advantage in terms of lower scheme fees on
transactions that self-acquirers routed directly to an issuer (“on-us”) as opposed to the
scheme fees associated with the traditional flow of transactions via an acquirer (“off-us”).
However, shortly after Countdown began acting as a self-acquirer, changes were made by a
scheme to remove any pricing differential between on-us and off-us credit transactions,
largely eliminating the financial advantage associated with self-acquiring.
While Countdown noted that being a self-acquirer has given it the benefit of being able to
directly negotiate with issuers in respect of interchange, it stated that, given the current
pricing structure, it may not have made the decision to self-acquire. Countdown also noted
that in the absence of any regulated access rules, not all issuers have agreed to participate
in Countdown's self-acquiring model. The investment required to become a self-acquirer,
combined with the new pricing structure of one of the schemes and the lack of stipulated
35
See, for example, Canadian Competition Tribunal. (2012). Closing Submissions of the Commissioner of
Competition in the matter certain agreements or arrangements implemented or enforced by Visa
Canada Corporation and MasterCard International Incorporated. Retrieved from
http://www.ct-
tc.gc.ca/CMFiles/CT-2010-010_Closing%20Argument%20of%20the%20Commissioner%20of%20
Competition_303_45_7-5-2012_6244.pdf
36
In addition, annual fees are a fixed revenue source, whereas rewards are variable depending on
spend, so there would be inefficiencies associated with the use of greater annual fees to fund rewards.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
53
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
access rules, has had the effect of making it appear highly unlikely that any other self-
acquirers will enter the New Zealand market. This means that issuers and schemes are
unlikely to face any real pressure to reduce interchange rates and caps via this mechanism.
10
Do you agree that self-acquirers are unlikely to place downward pressure on
interchange?
201. Section 3.2.4 noted that merchants do have some ability to negotiate down the MSF
they face, but pointed out that this ability to negotiate is largely limited to negotiating
over the extent of the acquirer’s mark-up over the interchange rate. In addition, large
merchants are able to place some downward pressure on the interchange rates they
face. However, these efforts to date have not been large enough to make an appreciable
difference to the overall price incentives faced by consumers. We do not foresee any
market developments in the near future that would substantially increase merchants’
ability to negotiate down MSFs or interchange on credit cards, and in doing so, reduce
the level of distortion of price signals that currently exists.
202. This is because, as long as credit card rewards exist at their current rates, many
consumers will not see other payment methods (such as debit cards or direct entry
payment methods) as direct substitutes. In fact, the recent growth in rewards, to the
extent that it is sustained, will serve to widen the distinction between credit cards and
other forms of payment that do not attract rewards. The less that other payment
products are seen as competitive substitutes to credit, the more consumers will demand
the ability to pay with credit, and the less bargaining power a merchant will have over
MSFs. We think that this dynamic, combined with the migration of consumers to cards
that attract higher interchange, may explain the recent rise in MSFs for small and
medium-size merchants.
203. As long as merchants feel compelled to accept credit card payments (due to consumer
demand), the schemes will face little incentive to reduce interchange caps, because to
do so would make other schemes’ products more attractive to issuers and, in turn,
consumers. For the same reasons, there is little reason to believe that issuers will
unilaterally choose to reduce the interchange they charge within these caps when doing
so would harm their ability to attract consumers.
11
How much negotiating power do merchants have over the merchant service fees they
face? Is this likely to change in the future?
4.2.6 This is a long-standing economic distortion that is growing
204. The issues relating to high-cost credit card payments, allocative inefficiency, and cross-
subsidies in relation to credit card transactions are long-standing. Long-run weighted
average interchange rates for credit card transactions fluctuate, with some recent
growth, but are not rising sharply. Similarly, as noted in Section 3.2.2, the value of
rewards for New Zealand credit cards appears to have remained reasonably consistent
until last year, when rewards grew (and many annual fees were waived) following the
renegotiation of the Air New Zealand Airpoints programme with banks.
205. Even at their current level, we think that the issues described here represent an
unnecessary economic distortion that there is merit in addressing. These issues are
largely independent of the investment and innovation in credit card products that is,
reducing the level of inefficiency in the market should not have a negative impact on
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
54
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
innovation. Moreover, there is also evidence that the overall level of distortion is
increasing. As noted in Section 3.2.2, we know that there has been an overall
premiumisation of cards of late, with more cards attracting higher rewards, interchange,
and MSFs, and therefore potentially increasing allocative inefficiency and cross-subsidies
above the estimates provided in this section.
12
Do you think that the issues in the credit card market are of a scale that warrants
intervention? If not, do you think that the size of the issue is likely to grow over time?
4.2.7 Summary
206. In summary, the current inducements to use credit cards substantially distort price
signals which result in a greater use of economic resources to process retail payments
and a cross-subsidy from users of low-cost payment methods to high-cost users. It
appears unlikely that this dynamic will be resolved by market mechanisms in the
foreseeable future in fact the dynamics inherent in the market may actually serve to
exacerbate this issue over timemeaning that government intervention may be
required to resolve this issue.
Inefficiencies could develop in the debit market 4.3
4.3.1 The growth of scheme-based debit payments creates cause for concern…
207. In addition to the issues in the credit market, the debit market could also be heading in a
direction that would not deliver good overall outcomes for consumers. As Figures 3 and
4 demonstrate, the debit market is currently dominated by transactions that are
switched to issuer (proprietary EFTPOS and inserted/swiped scheme debit), although the
use of switch-to-acquirer and the associated interchange business model is growing
rapidly as a result of the growth of contactless and online transactions.
208. The share of contactless transactions will continue to grow as more merchants start
accepting contactless debit payment. We predict that the share of card-present
transactions made contactlessly could increase to at least 60 per cent of all debit
transactions by 2024 (compared to around 15 per cent currently, and around 2 per cent
in January 2014).
37
However, ultimately, the level of growth will depend on the following
interrelated factors:
The financial incentives for use set by schemes, issuers, and acquirers.
The level of pressure from consumers for contactless payment.
The extent of growth of online purchases.
The development of technology that encourages contactless payment, such as
mobile apps.
The levels of merchant acceptance.
209. There are real benefits associated with contactless technology for both consumers and
merchants. However, because of the commercial model that underpins it, the growth of
contactless transactions creates cause for concern due to:
37
We consider this to be reasonably conservative, assuming steady growth in merchant acceptance. For
example, liner modelling based on current trends would actually place contactless debit usage at more
than 70 per cent of all debit transactions by 2024.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
55
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
The potential for schemes, issuers and acquirers to increase interchange and MSFs as
contactless payment becomes entrenched and price sensitivities of consumers and
merchants change.
The potential for cross-subsidies and a negative impact on allocative efficiency, as
with the use of credit cards.
The possibility that the schemes’ interchange business model limits uptake of cheap
or innovative payment options by consumers.
4.3.2 …and many participants face incentives to encourage its uptake…
210. Many participants face an incentive to encourage the uptake of contactless payment.
Firstly, it is in the interests of schemes to increase the volume of contactless
transactions. This is because the schemes receive revenue from issuers and acquirers
when transactions are processed via switch-to-acquirer, as contactless is. In doing so,
the schemes are competing with each other’s products, as well as with proprietary
EFTPOS (and other payment methods). Thus, in order to grow consumer usage, the
schemes need to balance the interchange cap set to ensure that issuers are incentivised
to issue their product to consumers over proprietary EFTPOS, while ensuring that
charges to acquirers (and then merchants) do not harm (and promote) the acceptance
of contactless products.
211. Secondly, it is also in the interests of issuers to increase the volume of contactless
transactions. This is because they receive revenue from the associated interchange fee.
Issuing banks receive no such revenue from proprietary EFTPOS or swiped/inserted
scheme debit transactions. In fact, these latter transactions cost banks (see below).
Issuers are also responding to consumer demand for scheme debit cards on the basis of
their greater functionality (i.e. they can be used internationally and online). While many
of the transactions that take place on these scheme cards will not attract a revenue
source immediately, they know that the percentage of revenue-earning transactions will
increase quickly as contactless uptake increases.
212. We also expect that consumer pressure for contactless acceptance will continue to
grow. This pressure is completely rational from the perspective of an individual
consumer. Contactless payment is more convenient for the consumer, and as with credit
cards (see Section 4.2 above), consumers do not face the direct costs of this added
convenience. The time saving provided by contactless payment is marginal (though
proportionately more important in short-interaction contexts such as bars or fast-food).
Nevertheless, contactless payment does offer a better customer experience. While
subtle, many merchants are likely to be conscious of the negative impression a customer
receives when they expect to be able to pay contactlessly only to find that they cannot.
213. Finally, the merchant’s decision whether to accept contactless payment depends on
whether they consider the additional cost to justify the benefits that accrue to them. In
this case, relevant factors may include:
Whether acceptance of contactless payment would increase sales.
Whether the time saving that results from the use of contactless payment is valuable
in the context of the merchant’s business model.
If contactless payment displaces another payment option, the cost or saving of that
incremental change. For example, shifts from proprietary EFTPOS and
inserted/swiped scheme debit and cash to contactless debit payment will cost the
merchant, but shifts from credit card to contactless debit will save the merchant
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
56
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
money. It seems likely, however, that the former shifts involving added cost (from
EFTPOS and cash) will outweigh the latter shift involving savings (from credit).
214. In addition, as more merchants accept contactless payment, the remaining merchants
will face increasing competitive pressure to also do so. This is being driven by larger,
“strategic” merchants taking up contactless payment, partly in response to bank and
scheme incentives, including significantly lower interchange rates compared to smaller
merchants and rebates directly from the schemes. This pressure to accept contactless
payment arises because consumers more frequently shop at strategic merchants (such
as supermarkets) and come to expect this option when they shop elsewhere.
13
Do you agree with our assessment of the incentives held by different parties in relation
to debit card usage?
4.3.3 …but there is little incentive to invest in proprietary EFTPOS
215. Just as dial-up internet was long left behind as a competitor to broadband, proprietary
EFTPOS is quickly reaching the stage where its limited functionality (and security) means
that it is no longer an effective competitor to scheme cards. This lack of innovation is
largely due to the incentives on the banks that have evolved as the EFTPOS system
developed. There is no “owner” of proprietary EFTPOS – it is not a scheme that seeks to
compete for market share. At present, the banks:
Own Paymark, the switch that processes around three-quarters of electronic
transactions (the remainder are largely processed by Verifone, formerly owned by
ANZ).
Have a majority on the Board of Payments New Zealand and on its Consumer
Electronic Clearing System committee.
Are card issuers, providing EFTPOS and scheme debit cards to consumers.
216. As it stands, Paymark’s main business is to act as a switch for transactions. From the
outside, it appears that its shareholders have little incentive to support or fund other
activities, such as the development of online EFTPOS or greater functionality of non-
scheme payment cards. This is because issuing banks do not receive a revenue stream
from proprietary EFTPOS transactions, and therefore directly carry the cost of
processing the EFTPOS transactions made by the cards they issue. Any investment in
Paymark therefore represents a direct cost to the banks.
217. Payments New Zealand had previously undertaken work to explore adding greater
functionality to proprietary EFTPOS, but has largely abandoned this work due to
conflicting interests among its shareholders, directors and participants.
218. On the other hand, as already discussed, issuers of scheme debit cards receive
interchange revenue each time the scheme debit card is used contactlessly. As it stands,
this makes contactless scheme debit products sufficiently attractive to justify not
investing in the upgrades to the proprietary EFTPOS scheme that would be required to
make it a viable competitor.
14 Do you agree that there is little incentive to invest in proprietary EFTPOS?
4.3.4 Merchants will face an increase in costs …
219. The free”-to-merchant proprietary EFTPOS business model that has prevailed in New
Zealand for nearly 30 years has had the effect of making it effectively unviable to charge
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
57
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
merchants for inserted or swiped scheme debit transactions. When scheme debit was
introduced, the schemes and issuers understood that doing so would substantially limit
acceptance by merchants when, in the card-present context, proprietary EFTPOS and
scheme debit are substantively equivalent. It is only the introduction of contactless
debit, arguably an added service at the point of sale, which allowed the schemes and
banks to introduce the interchange business model to mainstream debit transactions
when it was previously confined to online and international debit transactions.
Box 5: Will schemes start imposing interchange on swiped/inserted scheme debit?
One of the concerns aired by merchants is that once scheme debit products are sufficiently
embedded in the New Zealand market, schemes could start switching these transactions to
acquirers and apply interchange, increasing costs for merchants. In our discussions with
them, schemes have been adamant that they will not introduce interchange on scheme
debit. If they were to do so, they argue that many merchants would either stop accepting
their cards or surcharge, and that many consumers would move back to proprietary EFTPOS.
This appears to be the case. Given the relatively rapid increase in contactless payment, there
is little need for the schemes and issuers to risk reducing acceptance of their product by
applying interchange when revenues are already rising relatively rapidly through the
increased use of contactless debit.
Nevertheless, there are scenarios such as if banks were to stop issuing proprietary EFTPOS
cards and thereby remove this payment method as a competitive constraintthat it could
be advantageous to schemes and issuers to start applying interchange. For this reason, it
may be beneficial for schemes and issuers to make their intentions clear to the market.
15
Do you agree that it is unlikely that schemes will start imposing interchange on
swiped/inserted scheme debit transactions?
220. An immediate impact of proprietary EFTPOS gradually losing market share to contactless
scheme debit is an increase in the overall cost to merchants for transactions to be
processed. This increase in cost is not tied to the contactless technology, but to the
interchange business model that it utilises. Based on current uptake, the cost to
merchants of accepting contactless debit was likely around $36 million in the 12 months
to March 2016.
38
If 60 per cent of card-present debit payments were made
contactlessly, the annual cost to merchants of accepting contactless debit could
increase to $252 million.
39
221. This projection assumes no change to the contactless interchange fee or MSFs charged
by acquiring banks. In fact, in the short-term, it seems plausible that interchange and
associated MSFs on contactless debit may fall further in order to drive greater
acceptance. Costs to merchants will nevertheless increase over time as a greater
proportion of payments attract MSFs. As with credit card interchange, the relative
38
Based on switch data and Retail NZ MSF estimations. The $36 million estimate uses different MSF
assumptions to the $461 million estimate of total MSFs in Section 3.2.4, but it conceptually forms part of
the $461 million total (rather than being on top of it). The $36 million does not include the cost of card-
not-present debit payments (which are captured in the data as credit transactions).
39
Based on MBIE uptake modelling and Retail NZ MSF estimations. This figure assumes no change to
MSFs, retail sales, or electronic transactions as a proportion of total retail sales. It does not include the
cost of card-not-present debit payments.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
58
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
burden of the cost increases will be more severe for smaller merchants, given the higher
MSFs they face on average.
222. Merchants are, as would be expected, concerned about the increase in cost to their
business that they will face as a result of accepting contactless payment. However, we
do not, in itself, see this as a problem (see Box 6).
Box 6: The impact of freeEFTPOS on innovation
The discussion about how the interchange business model will drive outcomes in the debit
payment market should not be read as an endorsement of the “free” pricing of proprietary
EFTPOS. Domestic EFTPOS was the most efficient debit payment option for a long time,
particularly compared to the main contenders at the time (cash and cheques). Given how
advanced the system was at the time it was introduced, there was limited gain in
investment to develop successor systems.
However, what was essentially the ‘under-pricing’ of EFTPOS created significant barriers to
enter the debit payment market. It also meant that the system received only the bare-
minimum level of investment, with few improvements to security or functionality over the
last 30 years, despite improving technology and increasing consumer expectations. Overall,
the legacy of the freepricing strategy is the inability of domestic EFTPOS to compete with
scheme debit.
16
Do you agree that merchants facing a per-transaction charge for accepting debit
payments is not an issue in itself?
4.3.5 …but the system-wide efficiency implications are less clear
223. Arguably more relevant to the efficiency of the system as a whole is the increase in
resource costs arising from the shift from proprietary EFTPOS to contactless debit. Using
the RBA’s resource cost data, the increase in resource cost to the system for each
average-sized transaction will be around 14 cents. At 60 per cent contactless uptake, we
estimate that the increase in resource cost to the economy arising from the use of
contactless payment instead of proprietary EFTPOS would be $97 million annually.
40
224. It should be noted that this comparison of resource cost relates to the cost of running
the systems as they stand. They do not address questions of price, or the level of
investment that would be required to support innovation and the development of
proprietary EFTPOS to a comparable standard to contactless debit.
41
This lack of
reinvestment is a key reason why the card schemes are now able to easily gain market
share, even though they are imposing an explicit cost for contactless debit transactions.
225. It is therefore not possible to make a strong judgement about the cost-effectiveness of
the shift towards scheme contactless debit, given the ongoing investment that would be
required to upgrade the proprietary EFTPOS system to allow it to compete with scheme
debit (again, assuming constant MSFs). In other words, while this short-term burden of
increasing costs associated with the shift to contactless payment will be directly borne
by merchants (and passed onto consumers through overall higher prices) it is not clear
40
This increase in cost is potentially conservative, given that it may overstate the cost of the New
Zealand proprietary EFTPOS system.
41
It has been suggested to us that the revenue required to maintain and invest in EFTPOS over time
would be a couple of additional cents per transaction.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
59
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
that the net increase in system costs (including scheme, issuer, acquirer, merchant and
consumer resource costs) is unreasonable given the sustained lack of investment in
proprietary EFTPOS.
17
Is the shift towards contactless debit cost-effective, taking into account the costs and
benefits to all parties in the system?
226. Even though it is inherently more costly to process a scheme contactless transaction
than an equivalent proprietary EFTPOS transaction, this would not be inefficient in itself
if the use of scheme products was the result of clear price signals to consumers.
However, this is not the case. As with credit cards, consumers do not face accurate price
signals when deciding to make a contactless transaction. This occurs at both ends of the
market. We know that surcharging is virtually non-existent for contactless payments,
and at the fringes (such as Westpac’s AirPoints Debit MasterCard) – cardholders are
being subsidised to use contactless cards through interchange.
227. This means that the choice of which payment option to use will not be made by
consumers based on the relative costs of each option, as they will lack the relevant price
signals. The choice between payment options will instead be heavily influenced by
schemes, issuers and acquirers, based on the relative profitability of each payment
option, with these participants being able to determine the relative prices for consumers
and merchants. This includes the ability to require merchants to pay an interchange fee
(through their acquiring bank) to the card issuer. As with the credit market, the lack of
price signals can therefore be expected to lead to allocative inefficiency as the use of the
interchange business model in the debit market grows.
42
228. In addition, as with credit, there will also be a cross-subsidy associated with the use of
contactless debit, as merchants increase prices across the board. Given the lower
average MSF on contactless debit, the cross-subsidy will be lower than for credit,
although still non-trivial.
18
Do you agree that the lack of price signals in the debit market is likely to lead to
inefficient outcomes of a similar nature to those in the credit card market?
4.3.6 Increases in interchange fees and MSFs seem likely in the medium term
229. As with credit, schemes and banks (as issuers and acquirers) have significant scope to
compete for consumer volume, either by absorbing the cost (waiving card fees) or going
further by making the effective price of using their product negative, by offering rewards
or other inducements. This can be done by bidding up interchange fees, to allow card
issuers to compete for consumers, as long as merchants remain relatively insensitive to
price.
42
Having said this, there could also be a decrease in allocative efficiency as the use of proprietary
EFTPOS declines. If it is accepted that merchants should face a per-transaction cost from their bank for
accepting payment via proprietary EFTPOS (and not all stakeholders do), then the lack of price signals on
EFTPOS from the acquirer to the merchant creates a level of allocative inefficiency in itself. Therefore,
the overall impact on allocative efficiency depends on the net effect of a) a reduction in allocative
inefficiency as the number of transactions that are ‘under-priced’ to merchants by acquirers reduces;
and b) an increase in allocative inefficiency as the number of transactions that are ‘under-priced’ to
consumers by merchants increases.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
60
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
230. In addition to this outcome arising through an increase in competition within the
interchange model, it may also arise through a reduction in competitive pressure from
outside of the model (i.e. as proprietary EFTPOS and inserted/swiped scheme debit
usage reduces). There has been a recent decline in interchange caps for contactless
debit, as schemes work to increase acceptance of the contactless payment by
merchants. However, as consumers become more accustomed to paying with
contactless, the pressure on merchants to accept contactless payments will grow. As
with credit, this effectively means that merchants’ negotiating power with acquirers
(and acquirers’ negotiating power with issuers and schemes) will reduce.
231. Therefore, once a certain threshold of acceptance is reached, we think there is likely to
be an increase in the level of interchange (and MSFs) on contactless debit, entrenching
the allocative inefficiency and cross-subsidy issues discussed above, and ultimately
further increasing the prices paid for goods and services by consumers.
19
Do you agree that merchant service fees are likely to increase for contactless debit once
acceptance reaches a certain threshold?
4.3.7 New entrants will likely need to offer interchange revenue to issuers
232. A corollary of the dynamics that are facilitating the replacement of proprietary EFTPOS is
that any serious potential competitor to contactless payment will need to offer a
revenue stream to induce banks to issue their cards (or other payment mechanisms,
such as mobile payment applications). Aside from devising an exceptionally superior
product, any new entrant will have to offer a competitive income stream to issuing
banks to what they currently receive under the scheme model. This draws out a broader
point: the issuing bank will be a barrier to the uptake of any potential new payment
system as long as the bank is in control of access to the consumer’s bank account.
233. There are three caveats to this, in which a mainstream business model could be
developed without relying on the interchange business model:
Firstly, banks may not always remain in control of the bank account. While banks
might resist third-party direct entry, there are already third party providers in the
card-not-present space such as Poli that utilise direct entry methods despite this
resistance.
Secondly, consumers could hold secondary accounts with non-bank providers such as
PayPal themselves, mitigating the need for banks to provide access to a consumer’s
main account.
Thirdly, banks might consider there to be strategic advantages from there being a
strong competitor to scheme products. This could include limiting the ability of
schemes to increase scheme fees, or attracting consumers from competing banks.
234. However, the likelihood of these three scenarios having a significant impact is limited by
the following factors:
Issuers or non-bank payment providers are likely to require some level of revenue
from their product, as a strategic advantage is not useful if the business is not making
any money. There are seemingly a limited number of scenarios in which a consumer
would be willing to pay to use the product, given that existing mainstream card-
based products are largely free to use.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
61
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
As noted in Section 3.1.2, it seems unlikely that many consumers would switch bank
or utilise a competing payment service on the basis of a superior debit product alone,
unless it was vastly superior.
Relatedly, the network effects required to sustain an effective payment platform are
likely to be difficult to achieve the withdrawal of Snapper in Wellington for store-
based payments is seemingly one example of this.
This situation is different to the high cost of cash and cheques that motivated the
development of EFTPOS even if the cost of debit scheme fees to the banks became
significant, banks wouldn’t necessarily have the incentive to build an alternative
together because there is a revenue flow associated with the interchange model that
there wasn’t with cash or cheques.
Finally, even if there is an incentive for a particular bank to develop new products
that do not utilise an interchange model, they will still need to bilaterally negotiate
access to other banks’ systems to achieve a workable network. This could be difficult
to achieve.
20
Do you agree with our assessment that the interchange business model imposes
significant barriers to entry in the debit market?
4.3.8 A number of unknowns will affect how the market will develop
235. The upshot of the dynamics discussed above is that:
Contactless debit payment, and the associated interchange model, is likely to
become pervasive in a relatively short timeframe.
Competition within the interchange model will ultimately distort price signals and
increase overall prices of goods and services for consumers.
There are significant impediments to the successful emergence of a mainstream
competitor that does not rely on the interchange model.
236. Nevertheless, unlike the credit market, where the issues discussed above have existed
for some time, there are a number of unknowns that make it uncertain how the debit
market will unfold. These include:
The level of take-up of contactless payment through mobile phones such as Apple
Pay. Such payment options (which utilise scheme rails) are still in their infancy or
awaiting a New Zealand launch. If such payments gain popularity, and consumers
start expecting to be able to use their mobile wallets exclusively (leaving cash and
their payment cards behind), merchants will face greater pressure to accept
contactless payment.
Whether new interchange-based payment options enter the market. While we have
recently seen the introduction of China UnionPay to the New Zealand market
(primarily for the benefit of Chinese tourists), the network effects of a payment
system make it difficult for new participants to gain traction. In any case, it is unclear
whether additional participants that utilise the existing business model would
actually improve outcomes, given the natural upward pressure on interchange.
Whether non-interchange-based payment methods enter the market. As noted
above, barriers to entry are high, and new products would likely need to be a step-
change above the status quo if they are to gain traction. Nevertheless, it is possible
that payment options could be offered by existing businesses in other sectors, such
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
62
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
as social media platforms or other apps. Depending on the underlying rails, these
could utilise a significantly different business model, which could alter the dynamics
and outcomes of the overall market.
Whether proprietary EFTPOS exits the market altogether. It has been suggested
that if the costs to banks of maintaining the proprietary EFTPOS system reach a point
where they exceed the benefits (for example, if levels of fraud on these cards start to
increase), banks could individually make the decision to stop issuing them. This could
reduce the competitive constraint on scheme debit fees paid to schemes, although
for this reason banks may be incentivised to keep proprietary EFTPOS around.
Whether merchants start to steer and surcharge more. Greater use of these
techniques by merchants could lead to consumers using lower cost payment options.
Given the barriers discussed in Section 3.2.6, this seems unlikely, but could occur if
MSFs continue to increase.
21 How do you think the debit market is likely to evolve in respect of these ‘unknowns’?
4.3.9 Summary
237. While the exact outcomes in the debit market over the medium-term are far from
certain, the likely upshot of the dynamics discussed above is that contactless debit
payment, and the associated interchange model, is likely to become pervasive over a
relative short timeframe. Over time, competition between schemes and the
entrenchment of the interchange model may ultimately distort price signals and
increase overall prices of goods and services for consumers.
238. There is seemingly little prospect of the successful emergence of a competitor that does
not rely on the interchange model. This makes it unlikely that these emerging issues
should they develop as expected will be resolved by the market alone, meaning that
government intervention may be necessary in the future. As noted in Annex 1, Australia,
the United States, and the European Union have chosen to regulate interchange levels
for debit.
There is a large gap between the MSFs faced by small and large 4.4
merchants
239. The data provided to us by banks suggest that there is a large and wideningspread in
the MSFs faced by merchants of different sizes, with interchange rates for small
merchants being around two and a half times the rate of the interchange rates for large,
‘strategic’, merchants. This spread of costs means that smaller merchants face a
competitive disadvantage with their customers relative to large merchants.
240. However, discussions with industry suggest that, while the gap between large and small
merchants has increased, it has not increased to the extent that the data suggests. This
is because, prior to the expiry of the Commerce Commission’s settlement, large
merchants received significant rebates from acquirers that weren’t captured in these
figures. Following the expiry of the settlement, these rebates were reduced, and large
merchants went directly to the schemes to negotiate reductions in the headline
interchange rate that they faced.
241. Differences in bargaining power (and thus cost faced) between small and large
merchants are pervasive across a number of industries. As one example, major users of
electricity face much lower energy tariffs than households and small businesses. Often
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
63
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
these differences reflect the lower average cost, and greater benefit, that sellers face
from servicing larger buyers.
242. It is therefore to be expected that acquirers would face different costs between
servicing large and small merchants, and therefore that a MSF might be justifiably higher
for a smaller merchant on the basis of these costs. However, it is difficult to understand
why interchange should vary between different sized merchants on a cost basis. This is
because the costs funded out of interchange (principally rewards) seemingly do not
differ based on the size of the retailer.
243. If the spread were to increase further, we are concerned that the competitive
disadvantage faced by smaller firms could ultimately harm retail competition. While we
see the spread in fees as being part of the broader issue relating to the credit card
market, any government intervention to address the issues identified in this Issues
Paper should nevertheless consider the impact on the spread of MSFs.
22
Do you consider the extent of the difference in the interchange relating to small and
large merchants to be justified?
Box 7: Can MSF pricing be made clearer to merchants?
It was clear in the discussions we had with merchants that there could be greater clarity in
the fees and charges they were paying. Some merchants noted that the information
provided by schemes, banks, switches and terminal providers could be conflicting. There
may therefore be opportunities to ensure that basic information is consistent and correct.
Merchants also noted that some banks do not separate out the cost of credit and debit
transactions, or make clear the impact of accepting contactless payment. These concerns
were shared by both small and large merchants, indicating that scale alone does not ensure
that merchants can understand the information they receive.
We have already noted that merchants are not making use of unbundled rates. While this
could be in part due to a lack of merchant understanding that unbundled rates are available
or potentially advantageous, better information could allow merchants to surcharge or steer
customers more effectively, and better negotiate fees with their acquirer. This breakdown
of information would be useful for these purposes regardless of whether the retailer
chooses to adopt a bundled or unbundled MSF.
It should be noted that while greater transparency would provide merchants with a better
understanding of what they are paying, it is unlikely to resolve the wider issues discussed in
Section 4 above.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
64
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
Assessment against objectives 4.5
244. The following table summarises the issues discussed so far against the objectives
outlined at the beginning of this Issues Paper, that:
Objective One: There is innovation and development of payment options that are
valued by consumers and businesses.
Objective Two: Resources are allocated efficiently at a system level. In the context of
retail payments, this means that the mix of transaction methods used represents the
underlying preferences of consumers and merchants, taking into account the
marginal benefits and costs of certain forms of payment to the system as a whole.
Objective Three: The cost associated with payment systems is distributed fairly
across consumers and merchants at an individual level.
Table 6: Assessment of outcomes against objectives
Market
Objective One:
Innovation
Objective Two: Allocative
efficiency at a system level
Objective Three: Fair
distribution of costs to
consumers and merchants at
an individual level
Credit
No significant
concerns. The New
Zealand credit card
market benefits from
similar levels of
innovation seen in
overseas jurisdictions.
Significant concerns. The
muted price signals for
credit cards results in a
greater overall cost to the
New Zealand economy
than if there were clear
price signals.
Significant concerns. Firstly,
there is a mismatch of the costs
consumers face, and the
benefits they receive. Secondly,
a consequence of smaller
businesses’ weaker bargaining
power is that they bear a
greater burden of the costs than
larger businesses.
Debit Some concern.
Innovation has been
poor while “free”
EFTPOS was dominant.
The emergence of
contactless scheme
technology represents
an advance but its
entrenchment could
pose barriers to new
entrants.
Growing concern, but
future development
unclear. Around 85 per
cent of debit transactions
remain freeto
merchants. However, the
emerging dominance of the
interchange business
model could result in
inefficiencies in the future,
as currently seen in the
credit card sector.
Growing concern, but future
development unclear.
Contactless debit is cheaper for
merchants than credit cards,
meaning that any cross-subsidy
is lower. However, if rewards
were to become widespread, or
interchange were to increase,
then our concerns could
increase.
23 Do you agree with our assessment of the two markets against our proposed objectives?
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
65
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
5. Possible next steps
245. This section outlines our preliminary thinking on next steps to address the issues
identified in this Issues Paper. As noted in Section 4, we do not consider that market
forces are likely to resolve these issues. Therefore, we think that some form of
government intervention will be required if these issues are to be addressed.
246. The complexity of the retail payment system and the potential pace of change means
that it will be important for the following to be taken into account when developing a
way forward:
the New Zealand context;
the effectiveness and net benefits of each option;
any consequential impacts on consumers and merchants, investment in innovation,
and development of the broader retail payments sector; and
the timeliness of any intervention.
247. Should further work be undertaken, it would involve close engagement with
stakeholders, in order to ensure that any proposals make the best use of industry
expertise and take into account any stakeholder concerns.
Immediate actions 5.1
248. We have identified two immediate, industry-led actions that could improve the
transparency of the market as it is currently configured.
5.1.1 Acquirers could provide greater transparency about unbundled MSFs
249. The efficiency of the market could be improved if acquirers were to provide merchants
with greater information about MSFs, allowing merchants to:
Better negotiate with schemes and acquiring banks on the mix of payment options
and the fees incurred, and gain a better understanding of how fees for particular
payment options compares to the value they derive from them.
More effectively consider how to deliver payment options to consumers, including
through the use of surcharging and steering.
250. This could put some downward pressure on MSFs for those merchants who have the
requisite bargaining power, and improve price signals to consumers. These are desirable
market outcomes, regardless of any other intervention. However, the impact is likely to
be limited given the other incentives placed on the parties by the interchange business
model. We think that further intervention is likely to be required to address the wider
policy issues.
24
Would greater transparency have any material benefit for merchants or any other
parties in the system?
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
66
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
5.1.2 Schemes could publicly clarify their intentions in relation to charging for swiped
and inserted debit payments
251. Given the uncertainty merchants face around whether swiped/inserted scheme debit
transactions could one day attract interchange (see Box 5), we think that there would be
benefit in schemes publicly clarifying their intentions about whether or not they intend
to route transactions via scheme rails (and impose a fee on merchants).
25
Would there be any benefit in schemes publicly clarifying their intentions in relation to
charging for swiped and inserted debit payments?
Further work to address the wider policy issues 5.2
252. While useful, we think that these immediate actions would be unlikely to resolve the
wider policy issues discussed in detail in Section 4 above. We recommend a package of
further work to address the issues that the interchange business model brings to the
credit and debit card markets.
Box 8: Can the Commerce Commission address these issues?
The Commission noted in its evaluation of the 2009 settlement with schemes and banks that
parties had been complying with the settlement agreements, and therefore that they were
likely to be complying with the Commerce Act in respect of the issues that were considered
as part of the settlement. The Commission noted that if there were any residual issues
relating to retail payments remaining, these were likely to be driven by factors other than
non-compliance with the Commerce Act, and therefore alternative regulatory intervention
might be required.
The Commission has also considered the applicability of Part 4 of the Commerce Act, which
deals with economic regulation of firms with a high degree of market power. Under Part 4,
for economic regulation to be applied, there must be little or no competition in the relevant
market, and little or no likelihood of a substantial increase in competition. The Commission
considers that it is unclear whether these tests would be satisfied.
5.2.1 Assess the costs and benefits of applying interchange regulation
253. We consider that the nature and the scale of the inefficiencies in the credit card market
warrants an assessment of the costs and benefits of applying interchange regulation in
the credit market. This would include assessing the impacts of interchange regulation on
consumers and merchants, investment in innovation and any other consequential
effects. International experience indicates that this is likely to be the most effective
mechanism for addressing these issues. Placing a cap on credit interchange rates would
limit the ability for schemes and banks to use the interchange business model to alter
incentives on other parties, where doing so would lead to inefficient economic
outcomes.
254. While the impacts of interchange regulation need to be more formally assessed,
broadly, it would serve to reduce the MSFs paid by merchants, and would likely reduce
the generosity of rewards programmes offered by issuers. While placing a cap on
interchange would not directly impact on the revenues of card schemes, it would likely
impact on the volume of transactions made by cardholders, and could therefore
indirectly affect scheme revenues.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
67
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
255. Addressing these price distortions could at once improve the value for money that New
Zealanders receive overall in payment services (with the potential to avoid inefficiency
of $45 million per year) and reduce regressive wealth transfers to holders of reward-
offering cards (currently around $59 million per year). Interchange regulation could
support an increase in effective purchasing power for consumers, with the potential for
positive flow-on effects across the domestic economy.
256. The debit market is in a state of transition and it is possible that the inefficiencies
present in the credit market will not develop to the point of warranting interchange
regulation. Nevertheless, the stakes are potentially higher for debit transactions, which
have a larger market share than credit transactions. One option would be for
interchange regulation to only be triggered if certain thresholds such as a given market
share of scheme debit products or a particular interchange rate were reached.
257. Interchange regulation would require the establishment of formal regulatory
responsibility for the economic outcomes of payment systems within an existing
government agency. This would address the arguable current gap in the regulatory
landscape, and complement the present roles of the Reserve Bank and the Commerce
Commission in the payment systems space.
26 Do you think that the benefits of interchange regulation are likely to exceed the costs?
27 What unintended consequences could arise from interchange regulation?
28 Under what conditions, if any, should debit interchange rates be regulated?
5.2.2 Barriers to entry
258. We also think there is merit in undertaking a technical study of whether there are
barriers to entry or expansion for new debit payment options, particularly disruptive
options based on developing technologies. In addition to the economic barriers caused
by the interchange business model used by the schemes, there could be additional
barriers relating to:
The institutions, rules and standards governing payments.
Any technical constraints resulting from the way the physical and IT infrastructure is
configured.
259. Minimal barriers to entry and expansion would support the viability of products that do
not rely on the interchange business model (and therefore do not produce the
associated inefficiencies).
29
Aside from the financial barrier imposed by the interchange business model, what
barriers to entry for new debit payment products currently exist?
30 Are there good justifications for these barriers being in place?
31 Are there ways in which any unjustified barriers could be removed?
5.2.3 Investigate other options
260. In addition, we think there could be merit in investigating other options. These include:
Whether the governance of payment systems can be improved.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
68
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
Lighter-touch regulation, such as an industry code of conduct (as in Canada).
Changes that would be required to make EFTPOS a sustainable alternative to scheme
debit products, including technological improvements.
Whether the retail payment system, or a part of the system, should be treated like a
utility.
32 Is there merit in exploring options in addition to interchange and barriers to entry?
33 Have we missed any options?
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
69
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
Recap of questions
Section 1
1 Are these objectives for retail payment systems appropriate?
Section 2
2
Are there any other emerging payment methods that we have missed? If so, what is their
likely impact on the market?
Section 3
3 What explains the decline in the revolve ratio on credit cards?
4 Do you agree with our explanation of the rationale for interchange?
5 Have we accurately described the incentives on parties in relation to interchange?
6
Why are interchange rates falling for large merchants but increasing for small-medium
merchants?
7
Is the resource cost data robust? Is the Australian data likely to over-state or under-state
the costs of running New Zealand payment systems?
Section 4
8
Do you agree with the logic underpinning our assessment that there is inefficiency in the
credit card market?
9
Do you agree with the logic underpinning our assessment that there are regressive cross-
subsidies in the credit card market?
10
Do you agree that self-acquirers are unlikely to place downward pressure on
interchange?
11
How much negotiating power do merchants have over the merchant service fees they
face? Is this likely to change in the future?
12
Do you think that the issues in the credit card market are of a scale that warrants
intervention? If not, do you think that the size of the issue is likely to grow over time?
13
Do you agree with our assessment of the incentives held by different parties in relation
to debit card usage?
14 Do you agree that there is little incentive to invest in proprietary EFTPOS?
15
Do you agree that it is unlikely that schemes will start imposing interchange on
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
70
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
swiped/inserted scheme debit transactions?
16
Do you agree that merchants facing a per-transaction charge for accepting debit
payments is not an issue in itself?
17
Is the shift towards contactless debit cost-effective, taking into account the costs and
benefits to all parties in the system?
18
Do you agree that the lack of price signals in the debit market is likely to lead to
inefficient outcomes of a similar nature to those in the credit card market?
19
Do you agree that merchant service fees are likely to increase for contactless debit once
acceptance reaches a certain threshold?
20
Do you agree with our assessment that the interchange business model imposes
significant barriers to entry in the debit market?
21 How do you think the debit market is likely to evolve in respect of these ‘unknowns’?
22
Do you consider the extent of the difference in the interchange relating to small and
large merchants to be justified?
23 Do you agree with our assessment of the two markets against our proposed objectives?
Section 5
24
Would greater transparency have any material benefit for merchants or any other
parties in the system?
25
Would there be any benefit in schemes publicly clarifying their intentions in relation to
charging for swiped and inserted debit payments?
26 Do you think that the benefits of interchange regulation are likely to exceed the costs?
27 What unintended consequences could arise from interchange regulation?
28 Under what conditions, if any, should debit interchange rates be regulated?
29
Aside from the financial barrier imposed by the interchange business model, what
barriers to entry for new debit payment products currently exist?
30 Are there good justifications for these barriers being in place?
31 Are there ways in which any unjustified barriers could be removed?
32 Is there merit in exploring options in addition to interchange and barriers to entry?
33 Have we missed any options?
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
71
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
Annex 1: International experiences
261. This section of the Issues Paper provides a broad overview of the approach to regulation
taken in Australia, the US, the European Union/United Kingdom, and Canada.
262. Internationally, electronic payment usage is growing rapidly. As with New Zealand, the
electronic payments landscape is dominated by Visa and MasterCard. Overseas
governments have grappled with similar issues as identified in this Paper, and have
taken a number of different approaches to try and address them. Countries with mature
electronic payment systems have been increasing their regulatory oversight, and in
some cases directly intervening in the economic outcomes of their system.
263. Information about merchant service fees in different jurisdictions is generally not
published, so it is difficult to make comparisons. It is also difficult to make comparisons
internationally, given that a sizeable (but rapidly declining) portion of New Zealand’s
debit transactions currently incur no charges, which is not generally the case overseas.
Despite these limitations, Table 7 provides an indication of average merchant service
fees in New Zealand, Australia and the UK, based on research by Retail New Zealand.
Table 7: Average merchant fees in New Zealand, Australia, and the UK (Retail New
Zealand data)
2012 2013 2014 2015
New Zealand Proprietary EFTPOS 0.00% 0.00%
New Zealand Contactless debit 1.00% 1.00%
New Zealand Visa/Mastercard credit 1.40% 1.70%
UK – debit 0.32% 0.32% 0.32% 0.36%
UK – credit 0.97% 1.04% 1.00% 0.89%
Australia Proprietary EFTPOS (AUD) $0.10 $0.10 $0.10 $0.09
Australia Visa/Mastercard credit/debit 0.84% 0.83% 0.82% 0.78%
A1.1. Australia
264. Australia has regulated interchange fees since 2003. The rationale for regulation was
that card systems tended to have arrangements that detracted from the efficiency and
competitiveness of Australia’s payments system.
43
265. The Payments System Board (which is part of the Reserve Bank of Australia) was
established in 1998. The Board sets the Reserve Bank’s payment system policy to:
Control risk in the financial system.
Promote the efficiency of the payments system.
Promote competition in the market for payment services.
43
Reserve Bank of Australia. (2015). Review of Cards Payment Regulation: Issues Paper. Retrieved from
http://www.rba.gov.au/payments-and-infrastructure/review-of-card-payments-regulation/pdf/review-
of-card-payments-regulation-issues-paper.pdf
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
72
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
266. The Board has the power to ‘designate’ payment systems and to set standards and
access regimes for these systems (without further legislation). Currently the following
payment systems are designated:
Visa and MasterCard credit, debit and prepaid systems.
The American Express companion card system (a companion card is a credit card that
is linked to two different schemes e.g. one account with both Visa and American
Express functionality),
Australia’s proprietary EFTPOS systems.
267. Current regulation includes:
Setting weighted average interchange fees for credit and debit (currently 0.5 per cent
for credit and 12 cents for debit).
44
Allowing merchants to surcharge (more recently, it has modified its regulations on
surcharging to address instances of excessive surcharges in some industries).
45
Reducing barriers to entry.
Removing the ‘honour-all-products’ rule which required merchants who accepted a
scheme’s credit cards to also accept their debit cards.
268. The Board estimates that merchant payment costs have been reduced by $15 billion
relative to the amount merchants would have paid since 2004 if fees had remained at
pre-reform levels.
46
269. Over the course of its reviews, the Payments System Board reached a number of
conclusions about the effect of regulation:
Costs for merchants have reduced significantly.
The decrease in costs has not resulted in a decline in the quality of services offered to
consumers. Participants in the system have continued to innovate and Australia has
one of the highest rates of adoption of contactless payments in the world.
It is difficult to isolate the effect that regulating interchange has had on overall
prices, given fluctuating input prices for merchants and overall general inflation.
Despite this, the Board is of the view that the bulk of these savings for merchants
have, or will be, passed through in savings to consumers. This judgement is
consistent with standard economic analysis which suggests that, ultimately, changes
in business costs are reflected in the prices that businesses charge.
Advertised annual fees on credit cards increased somewhat following the reforms,
but declined in real terms in subsequent years.
270. Australia’s proprietary EFTPOS system has been the subject of significant investment in
recent years. This includes the implementation of contactless functionality that is
underway and online EFTPOS being developed. Its market share has fallen in recent
years, reflecting the adoption of contactless functionality offered by other scheme
44
The RBA recently announced that the debit benchmark would be lowered to 8 cents from 1 July 2017.
45
Surcharging is more prevalent in Australia than New Zealand, despite the lower interchange fees and
MSFs charged.
46
Reserve Bank of Australia. (2016). Review of Card Payments Regulation: Conclusions Paper. Retrieved
from
http://www.rba.gov.au/payments-and-infrastructure/review-of-card-payments-
regulation/pdf/review-of-card-payments-regulation-conclusions-paper-2016-05.pdf
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
73
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
cards. There has also been investment in the underlying infrastructure to support
centralised switching of payments, rather than relying on a series of bilateral
relationships between financial institutions.
A1.2. Canada
271. The Canadian credit market is dominated by Visa and MasterCard, with the interchange
rate for most credit cards sitting between 1.4 and 2 per cent. Canada also has a
domestic debit product, Interac, which offers online and contactless functionality
(although acceptance is limited). Interac currently operates under an order issued by the
Canadian Competition Tribunal which dictates that it must operate on a not-for-profit
basis.
47
This means that Interac only charges fees that are sufficient to cover its costs.
272. In terms of the schemes, the Competition Bureau attempted to bring antitrust action
against the schemes for engaging in price maintenance. This action was dismissed in
2013 by the Canadian Competition Tribunal. While the Tribunal found that Visa and
MasterCard’s conduct was influencing the price of credit card services upwards and
having an adverse effect on competition, in its view, regulation of the industry would
provide a more appropriate solution then any remedy that the Tribunal could provide.
273. Following the Competition Tribunal’s ruling, Finance Canada developed a code of
conduct for the card payments industry. The key elements of the Code include:
Increased transparency payment schemes and their participants are required to
work with merchants to ensure that merchant-acquirer agreements and monthly
statements include enough information and are easy to understand.
Clarifying that merchants may discount types of payment (but merchants are still
prohibited from explicit surcharging by schemes).
Premium credit and debit cards will only be given to consumers who apply for or
consent to such cards. Premium cards must only be given to ‘premium’ cardholders
(i.e. those who spend, or have more assets than the average).
Rules around how fees are set and varied. For example, merchants must be given 90
days’ notice before any variance to interchange. Following notice of a variance,
merchants may cancel their contract with the acquirer, without penalty.
Merchants are not required to accept new products. If a scheme introduces a new
product or service, the merchant will not be obliged to accept it. The merchant must
explicitly express consent. This also applies to contactless cards or terminals. This
provision has essentially halted the introduction of Visa debit in Canada.
274. Finance Canada monitors the implementation of the code and any voluntary
commitments made. For example, in 2014 Visa and MasterCard agreed to hold
interchange rates at 1.5 per cent for the next 5 years.
275. In the course of the work we have undertaken, schemes have pointed to the Canadian
voluntary code of conduct as an example of a successful model that New Zealand should
look to follow. The impact of the code of conduct has not been reviewed to date.
47
This order expires in June 2018. See http://www.ct-tc.gc.ca/CMFiles/CT-2013-
003_Order%20Varying%20and%20Restating%20the%20A_4_38_9-11-2013_4045.pdf
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
74
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
A1.3. United States
276. There has been a mixed approach to ensuring that payment systems in the United States
produce good economic outcomes. Debit rates are regulated by the Federal Reserve,
while the rules around credit have mostly evolved out of litigation.
277. There is a history of litigation in the United States against credit card companies. Key
features of the resulting credit market include:
Visa and MasterCard no longer impose a contractual no-surcharge rule on retailers
(as a result of a 2013 settlement between Visa, MasterCard and retailers).
48
However, nine states, which account for 40 per cent of the population, still have a
statutory no-surcharge prohibition.
Visa and MasterCard agreed to negotiate interchange fees in good faith (2013
settlement).
Honour-all-cards rules exist, however due to a settlement in 2003 with Wal-Mart,
Sears and other retailers, merchants who accept scheme debit do not have to
accept scheme credit.
Contractual restrictions on no-minimum purchase rules are restricted, enabling
merchants to set a minimum credit card purchase of up to $10.
Merchants can discount payment types, but not differentiate within payment types
(e.g. they can discount cash, but not Visa over MasterCard).
278. Debit card interchange rates were regulated in 2010 as part of a last-minute
amendment to broader financial reform. The purpose of regulation was to lower
merchants’ cost of accepting payment and to pass the cost savings onto consumers in
reduced prices.
279. The reforms require the Federal Reserve to set the debit interchange rate at a level that
is reasonable and proportional to the cost incurred by the issuer. The current debit rate
set by the Federal Reserve is 0.05 per cent of the transaction value, plus 21 cents per
transaction. These rules only cover large banks with more than $10 billion in assets, and
do not apply to credit card transactions. In comparison, unregulated credit interchange
rates for Visa and MasterCard are between 1.5 and 3.25 per cent, plus 10 cents per
transaction. The reforms also required that all debit cards be capable of being processed
across two networks, with the choice between these two being determinable by the
merchant.
280. A paper by a senior economist at Kansas Federal Reserve found that reforms have had
some of their intended effects, including enhancing competition among card networks
for merchants and reducing the burden on merchants of high interchange fees. It noted,
however, that some merchants who processed very small-value transactions had
actually seen increases in merchant service fees, and that overall impacts on consumer
welfare and overall economic efficiency were, at that point, unclear.
49
48
The settlement contained many conditions which may have limited the feasibility of surcharging. In
addition, this settlement has recently been rejected by the US Federal Court of Appeal.
49
Hayashi, F. (2013). The New Debit Card Regulations: Effects on Merchants, Consumers and Payment
Systems Efficiency.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
75
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
281. Another review
50
of the reforms found that the regulations:
Significantly reduced interchange income for affected banks.
Resulted in increased deposit fees which offset 30 per cent of the lost interchange
income.
Had no discernible impact on bank operating expenses or staff numbers.
A1.4. European Union
282. The European Union introduced a number of payment systems regulatory measures in
2015. These were achieved through the revised Directive on Payment Services (PSD2),
and through the Regulation on Multilateral Interchange Fees. The effect of this is that
member states must:
Regulate interchange fees.
Require acquirers to disclose to merchants the costs of accepting payment
associated with each transaction (i.e. unbundle).
Designate a competent authority to supervise interchange regulation and give it the
appropriate powers to enforce the regulation.
Support open access by ensuring that consumers have the right to use third-party
payments software to execute payments on their behalf. This means that third
parties have the right to use a consumer’s banks details to make ‘direct entry’
payments.
283. The interchange rates set by the European Union are based on a ‘Merchant Indifference
Test’. This is where the interchange fees are set at a rate which renders a merchant
indifferent to whether it accepts payment via card or cash from a one-time customer.
The current rates are:
0.2 per cent of the transaction for Visa and MasterCard consumer debit cards.
0.3 per cent of the transaction for Visa and MasterCard consumer credit cards.
284. In addition, surcharging for interchange-regulated cards has been banned. The rationale
for this is that where interchange fees are capped at such a low level and the costs of
accepting card transactions substantially reduced, surcharging is no longer justified.
285. The European Commission has taken a number of antitrust cases against schemes for
cross-border interchange since the 1990s. For example, in separate cases the European
Court of Justice confirmed that MasterCard and Visa’s interchange fees for cross-border
payments restricted competition in breach of the EU’s competition rules.
286. As member states are still in the process of implementing the regulation into domestic
law, it is not possible to reach any final conclusions on the impact of the regulation.
However, following the announcement, a number of banks in the United Kingdom have
significantly reduced the rewards paid to cardholders, citing the reduction in
interchange.
287. The European Commission considered that one of the benefits of interchange regulation
is that all consumers will face lower prices, as the cost savings are passed on in the form
50
Kay, B., Manuszak, M., & Vojtech, C. (2014). Bank Profitability and Debit Card Interchange Regulation:
Bank Responses to the Durbin Amendment. Retrieved from
https://www.bostonfed.org/payments2014/papers/Cindy_M_Vojtech.pdf
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
76
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
of lower prices. The expectation is that the pass-through from merchants will be greater
than from issuers.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
77
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
Annex 2: The Commerce
Commission’s 2009 settlement
289. The Commission’s settlement agreements resulted from its investigation into the setting
of credit card MSFs and associated rules imposed by Visa and Mastercard. The
Commission received numerous complaints from the retail sector regarding these fees
and rules.
290. Prior to the settlement, interchange fees were set by agreement between each of the
credit card schemes and card issuers. The Commission considered that this was anti-
competitive, inflated merchants’ costs, and led to higher prices for consumers. The
Commission also challenged a number of other provisions of the agreements between
card schemes and issuing banks, including:
‘No surcharge’ and ‘no discrimination’ rules, which prohibited surcharging of credit
card transactions, and certain forms of discrimination such as cash discounts
between card payments and other payments, and between cards from different
schemes and/or card issuers. The Commission considered that these rules eliminated
opportunities for merchants to create incentives for the card issuing banks to charge
lower interchange fees. For example, by prohibiting surcharging, the rules shielded
credit cardholders from the cost of their payment choice and prevented merchants
from recovering the cost or steering cardholders to a preferred method of payment.
The combined effect of these rules was that the credit card schemes and banks could
collectively set high interchange rates without fear that consumers would switch to
other payment options. This would flow through to higher prices for all consumers.
‘Access Rules’ which restricted who could act as an acquirer of Visa and MasterCard
transactions. The Commission considered that these rules were anticompetitive as
they hindered entry by specialist acquirers or self-acquirers (generally large
merchants), which reduced competition between the four main card-issuing banks
that acted as acquirers in New Zealand.
291. As a result of the Commission’s investigation, the Commission entered settlement
agreements with the banks and schemes, which included commitments to:
Significantly reduce the average interchange fees charged on New Zealand credit
card transactions, ensuring that these fees in New Zealand are driven downwards
from the rates that were centrally set by the Visa and MasterCard schemes.
Refrain from any standard contracting practices that prohibit merchants from
surcharging Visa and MasterCard credit cards as a condition of receiving credit card
acceptance services.
Refrain from any standard contracting practices that prohibit merchants from
encouraging customers to pay by other means.
Offer merchants the option of unblended service fees; that is offering separate fees
for Visa and MasterCard transactions, enabling merchants to see the costs of
accepting each scheme's credit cards.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
78
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
Offer the option of fully unbundled service fees as between all types of Visa and
MasterCard credit card transactions, revealing the exact amount of interchange fees
applicable to each card transaction, assisting merchants to negotiate lower service
fees and provide incentives to consumers to use their preferred payment methods.
Change the access rules so that acquirers of credit card transactions did not also have
to be card issuers or financial institutions.
Allow merchants to negotiate directly with issuers over the interchange charged
within a scheme’s interchange cap.
292. The Commission’s settlement also prevented schemes and acquirers from imposing
‘honour-all-products’ rules. This means that a merchant which accepts a scheme’s debit
cards does not also need to accept its credit cards. However, the settlement did not
restrict schemes and acquirers from imposing ‘honour-all-cards’ rules. This means that
schemes and acquirers are free to require merchants that accept one type of a scheme’s
credit card (e.g. Visa Standard) to also accept all other types of that scheme’s credit
cards (e.g. Visa Platinum).
51
51
Although a merchant could, in theory, set a very high surcharge for a particular form of credit card in
order to have the same effect as non-acceptance.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
79
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
Annex 3: List of stakeholders
293. We spoke to a range of stakeholders in preparing this Issues Paper. They included:
ANZ,
Westpac,
BNZ,
ASB,
Kiwibank,
TSB,
MasterCard,
Visa,
American Express,
Payments New Zealand,
Paymark,
Verifone New Zealand,
Consumer New Zealand,
New Zealand Bankers’ Association,
Retail New Zealand,
Traiteur European Butchery Christchurch,
Early Settler furniture,
Foodstuffs New Zealand,
Countdown,
Mitre 10,
Tim Duston, independent consultant,
Merco,
Buddle Findlay,
Wigley and Company solicitors,
Covec,
Xero,
Dominic White of Pebble Payments (independent reviewer),
Mike Laing of LWT Advisers (independent reviewer), and
Staff at the Reserve Bank of Australia.
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
80
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
Annex 4: Key figures used in this
Issues Paper
294. The following table summarises many of the figures used in this Issues Paper, and
explains at a high level what they refer to, and the assumptions used in their calculation.
All the figures used in this Issues Paper are rough estimates for illustrative purposes
only. Some of these are explicit charges, such as merchant service fees. Others are
implicit overall resource costs to the system. These measure different things, and cannot
be directly compared.
Table 8: Key figures used in this Issues Paper
Figure What this describes Data sources and assumptions
$76
billion
The value of transactions made on
payment cards across the economy
(not just the retail sector) in the 12
months to March 2016.
Stats NZ Electronic Card Transactions (ECT) data.
$461-589
million
The estimated range of merchant
service fees (MSFs) paid by merchants
in 2015 on both debit and credit.
$461 million is the weighted average MSF across both
debit and credit provided to us by a bank for the period
September 2015 to April 2016, applied across the total
value of credit card transactions in the year to March
2016 according to Stats NZ data (which also include
contactless and card-not-present debit).
$589 million uses Retail NZ survey data about MSFs for
debit and credit. It uses switch data to estimate the
number of debit transactions being misclassified as
credit transactions by Stats NZ, and applies the
estimated debit MSF to these transactions.
$36
million
The estimated MSF paid by merchants
in the 12 months to March 2016 on
contactless debit.
Uses switch data to estimate the number of debit
transactions being misclassified as credit transactions by
Stats NZ, and applies Retail NZ’s estimate of the average
debit MSF to these transactions. Conceptually forms
part of the $461-$589 million total MSF. Does not
include the cost of card-not-present debit payments
(which are captured in the data as credit transactions).
$252
million
The estimated MSF that would be
paid by merchants on contactless
debit if 60% of card-present debit
transactions are made contactlessly.
Uses the same figures as above for MSFs, retail sales,
debit transactions as a proportion of all electronic
transactions, or all electronic transactions as a
proportion of total retail sales. It does not include the
cost of card-not-present debit payments
.
$950
million
The annual resource cost of
processing card payments in New
Zealand. This includes authorisation
and transaction processing costs, fraud
and bad debts, scheme fees,
RBA Payment Costs study, converted into NZ$, and using
Statistics New Zealand data about the number of card
transactions and their average size. Understates credit
card resource costs because the average credit
transaction is larger than the average overall card
MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION & EMPLOYMENT
81
Retail Payment Systems in New Zealand: Issues Paper
Figure What this describes Data sources and assumptions
transaction tender time, and other
back-office costs. It does not include
the value of rewards, merchant service
fees, or profits.
transaction, but we use the resource cost for the
average-sized overall card transaction. May overstate
debit resource costs because the Australian EFTPOS
network is potentially more costly than New Zealand’s.
$137
million
The annual reduction in resource cost
that would be attained if all credit
card transactions were instead
proprietary EFTPOS transactions.
Stats NZ ECT data about number of credit card
transactions, multiplied by RBA’s estimate of resource
cost per average-sized transaction for credit cards, less
the cost per average-sized transaction for proprietary
EFTPOS.
$45
million
The annual reduction in resource cost
that would be attained if the people
who only use credit cards for rewards
instead used proprietary EFTPOS.
The above, less 20% to account for international and
business card transactions, which are unlikely to be
made on the basis of rewards, multiplied by 0.4 in
reflection of estimates that 40% of personal credit card
use is made primarily for rewards.
$97
million
The annual increase in resource cost if
60% of debit payments are made
contactlessly, relative to all of them
being made used proprietary EFTPOS.
Stats NZ ECT data about number of debit card
transactions, multiplied by RBA’s estimate of resource
cost per average-sized transaction for contactless debit
cards, less the cost per average-sized transaction for
proprietary EFTPOS. This increase in cost is potentially
conservative, given that it may overstate the cost of the
New Zealand proprietary EFTPOS system.
$187
million
The estimated annual increase in the
price of goods and services across the
economy as a result of the costs
placed on merchants to fund credit
card rewards.
Stats NZ data about credit card expenditure in the year
to March 2016, discounted by 10% to account for
transactions made by international cardholders. Based
on conversations and data from banks, we assume that
75% of credit card spending attracts rewards, that the
average value of rewards is 1% of expenditure, and that
20% of rewards are funded through annual fees.
$59
million
The estimated annual cross-subsidy
from low-income consumers to high
income consumers that occurs due to
the higher price they pay to fund their
credit card rewards.
Taking the above, we assume that only the highest-
earning 40% of households earn 100% of rewards. From
Stats NZ Household Economic Survey data, we estimate
that that these households are responsible for 68% of
retail expenditure. The resulting 32% of spending incurs
higher prices, but receives no reward, hence the cross-
subsidy.